Showing posts with label GSEs. Show all posts
Showing posts with label GSEs. Show all posts

Sunday, May 17, 2009

To us, that week, it looked very much like a run on the entire financial system

TO BE NOTED:

Sunday, May 17, 2009

How TARP Began: An Exclusive Inside View

May 14, 2009 04:01 PM ET | Rick Newman | Permanent Link | Print

When it first came into existence last September, TARP—the troubled assets relief program—sounded like just another ungainly government acronym. But since then, it has become an integral—and controversial—part of America's recession economy.

TARP's chief architect was Henry "Hank" Paulson, President Bush's treasury secretary, who led the financial rescue along with Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke and New York Fed Chairman Tim Geithner, who's now Paulson's replacement at treasury. Their initial plan was to use the $700 billion in TARP funding approved by Congress last October to purge financial firms of their so-called toxic assets.

[See why the banks still aren't fixed.]

But TARP morphed into an über-bailout that included direct cash injections into banks, the auto rescue, the AIG intervention, and other government efforts to revive the economy. If it sounds like a trial-and-error experiment, well, that's how it felt to the policymakers who designed it, too. "When we looked for easy solutions, we kept coming up empty," says David Nason, who was a senior Treasury Department official during the Bush administration. "Hank used to say all the time, 'We're going to have to do this with duct tape and fishing wire.' "

Nason and some of his Treasury colleagues did much of the jury-rigging, running doomsday scenarios, negotiating emergency deals with banks, wooing incredulous members of Congress, and devising ways to deal with problems once considered unthinkable. Frustrated Treasury Department officials, for instance, foresaw much of the carnage but found themselves poorly equipped to stop it. Anxious finance ministers from around the world began calling Treasury last summer to find out what the government planned to do about the developing crisis. The most tense moment may have been the September failure of Lehman Brothers, which occurred with alarming speed after British financial regulators scotched a takeover bid by the British bank Barclays.

[See 6 surprises from the recent bank stress tests.]

Nason and two other former Treasury officials, Philip Swagel and Kevin Fromer, spoke recently at a panel discussion sponsored by the Milken Institute. Their remarks form one of the most thorough accounts to date of how the government struggled to contain the worst financial crisis since the Great Depression. (See a video of the full discussion, which I moderated.) Here's a condensed version of their remarks:

David Nason, former assistant treasury secretary for financial institutions: The first inflection point was March 16, 2008, which was the acquisition date by JPMorgan Chase of Bear Stearns. The sheer time it took for this institution to go from viable to nonviable was breathtaking. Just two days before, the regulator [the Securities and Exchange Commission] had said Bear had adequate liquidity of $8 billion. This is an important inflection point because it was the first time the government had stood up and said we are going to support nonbanking institutions. We knew at that point the times had changed. We knew the policy ramifications were going to be very difficult and far reaching.

[See 5 signs the bailouts are getting better.]

We worried most significantly about the consequences of other similarly situated firms. It was a very trying and stressful time because when we looked for easy solutions, we kept coming up empty. The government did not have a ready-access pool of money to support or manage the resolution of financial institutions. The political climate was very challenging—at the time, people saw this as a bailout for fat cats on Wall Street. And there was some jurisdictional squabbling in Washington.

Philip Swagel, former assistant treasury secretary for economic policy: Right after Bear failed, the economy looked like it was actually in pretty good shape considering the problems in housing and the financial sector. Overall growth was positive, driven especially by exports. In the wake of Bear's failure, we looked at options, including many things that are now familiar: buying assets, insuring assets, buying pieces of pieces of institutions, in other words injecting capital, and a massive bailout from the bottom from refinancing every troubled homeowner. And we said those are all things you could write down, but back then, you had rebate checks that had been enacted but weren't yet going out, and we had positive growth. It would have been hard to imagine getting the authority to do those things or the approval from Congress for a contingency fund in case things got worse.

Nason: The next inflection point was July 2008. The government was worried about the big investment banks, CDS [credit-default-swap] spreads were blowing out, we were also worried about Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. These were some of the most leveraged institutions on Earth. Together, they had over $5 trillion in exposure if you consider the guarantee obligations that they had. Match that against about $60 billion in capital. We were also concerned that the housing correction was turning out to be significantly worse than the GSEs [government-sponsored enterprises, such as Fannie and Freddie] expected. We were very concerned that the GSEs were being overly optimistic about their ability to manage risk and withstand future losses.

[See the best and worst bailed-out banks.]

The GSE equity prices were getting punished during this time. More important to us, however, was the debt market. It was very clear to us there's no way the U.S. financial system is going to allow a firm the size of Fannie Mae to collapse( NB DON ). We were very worried about the trillions in debt they had outstanding, and what it would do to confidence if we let that debt go.

At this time, the Treasury was getting calls from finance ministers' offices from different parts of the world inquiring, "What is the government's relationship with Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac?" It's odd, but this appeared to be the first time that people were focusing on the fact that these are quasi-governmental institutions.

During this time period, the home loan banks, another GSE with similar exposure to the housing market, decided to postpone an auction. Every auction was something that we focused on and were worried about.

[See the banks most likely to pay back their bailout funds.]

We made the decision based on this set of circumstances that we had to support the GSEs. How were we going to do that? What did we have in our toolbox? Essentially nothing. We had about $2 billion of backup credit support for the GSEs. For $1.4 trillion organizations. This was clearly not enough to support these institutions in any real way. And we had no ability to provide any kind of equity support at all. So we decided we had to go up to Congress, bite the bullet, and ask for authority to backstop these institutions.

On July 30, 2008, the president signed a bill into law to provide equity support to these institutions. And we had the ability to support their debt up to the federal debt limit.

We made the judgment not to request the authority to nationalize the GSEs. It would have muddied the political discussion. I'm not sure we would have gotten the authority, and at this time, there wasn't a pressing need to do so. There's a long, tortured story about how the GSEs and Washington interface. But we wanted to have broad authority to support the GSEs and prevent their collapse.

[See why the auto bailout is a good model for other struggling firms.]

The entire month of September was an inflection point under my definition. But the first inflection point associated with September is Sept. 7, 2008, when the GSEs were forced into conservatorship. That came after regulators determined that they were drastically undercapitalized.

Two days later, AIG's stock fell 19 percent. Lehman's discussions to sell itself to the Korean Development Bank failed. The next day, Lehman put itself on the market for sale, with no clear takers. After some very tense discussions about whether there would be a purchaser, like JPMorgan was for Bear Stearns, we were very distressed to know that there were no takers.

So from the 10th to the 14th, the Federal Reserve, with the Treasury's support, decided to flush the system with liquidity. The Federal Reserve expanded the level of collateral the primary dealer credit facility would take, they increased the collateral that the term securities lending facility could take, and they increased the ability of banks to support nonbanking institutions. The government was putting "foam on the runway" to try to deal with what we were afraid of, which was how the market would react to a Lehman Brothers bankruptcy.

The next day, Lehman Brothers filed for bankruptcy.

The question is: Did we let Lehman Brothers fail? That assumes it was a choice that we made. The simple truth is that the government was presented with an institution with a $600 billion balance sheet, with enormous leverage. Confidence in the institution was virtually nonexistent. The only way to stabilize a firm under these circumstances is to stop a run on the institution, stop counterparties from claiming their debts should immediately come due. That was manageable in the Bear Stearns situation because someone was willing to guarantee all or most of those liabilities.

[See how bailouts can butcher capitalism.]

The public posture was that government support would not be available. But there wasn't a single credible buyer at the table who was turned away by us.

So when people ask, "Why did you let Lehman Brothers fail?" I ask, "What is the deal that the government turned down that would have prevented Lehman's failure?" If there's not someone willing to take on a balance sheet as large as that of Lehman Brothers, what is the government to do? The government has a few options: We have a lending facility at the Fed, you could provide a loan to them secured against collateral, or you could guarantee all their liabilities. That might have been the right decision, but we had no authority to do that before TARP.( NB DON )

Looking back, if we could have plugged some of the holes in our authorities, maybe this could have been done differently. I don't think we would have gotten those authorities if we had asked for them before September.

[See why the feds rescue banks, not homeowners.]

Of course, things continued to be unpredictable. We didn't predict that the U.K. bankruptcy process would essentially destroy all confidence in that funding model and that business model. And we didn't expect that the commercial paper market would essentially shut down because Lehman Brothers' commercial paper was impaired. Those two markets were the transmission vehicles that killed confidence, which we didn't expect.

That same day as Lehman, Bank of America acquired Merrill Lynch. We didn't have a second to catch our breath. The day after the Lehman bankruptcy, AIG got a $50 billion loan from the Federal Reserve. There was no significant discussion over whether the Federal Reserve was going to provide backup facilities to AIG because of two distinguishing characteristics: One, they were huge. They were global. They were bigger than Lehman Brothers. But the more important distinction is that the Fed is in the business of providing loans when it is "secured to its satisfaction." And AIG had the benefit of having solvent, highly regulated, very valuable insurance subsidiaries to which the Federal Reserve felt comfortable extending its loan facilities.

[See more companies likely to fail this year.]

After that we get to Sept. 17 2008, which was essentially the creation of the TARP concept. It was at that point that there was a meeting of the minds between Paulson, Bernanke, and Geithner that enough is enough, we're going to break the back of this crisis, and we're tired of not having the tools to deal with this crisis. And the judgment was made that we were going to ask for broad authority from Congress.

At that point, it was essentially 24-hour duty at the Treasury Department. Some people slept there.

Kevin Fromer, former assistant treasury secretary for legislative a ffairs: For context, this was a program about the size of the entire federal operating budget on an annual basis. Congress usually works through that process for 10 or 15 months, just to keep the lights on. We were asking Congress for $700 billion in basically a week or two. In the context of a national election. An election year is typically not the year to do big things.

We had one week left in the legislative calendar. It was not possible to do it in a week. I wasn't sure it was possible to do it at all. We needed to get somewhere fast, so we sent up the infamous three-page bill, which was draft legislative text the committees needed to start the discussions.

[See why the markets hate the idea of bank nationalization.]

Swagel: It was very difficult to say, if this shock happens, you will get this economic effect. In September, the nation as a whole didn't understand that what was happening in the credit markets would matter to them. There was this sort of Wall Street-Main Street divide. It was hard to explain to people why this mattered.

The week of Lehman and AIG, there was a panicked flight from mutual funds, and that led to a lockup in commercial paper. In our view, that was really the key, the CP market breaking down. That had a direct link to investment. Businesses use that to fund their daily operations. That would lead to a direct plunge in business spending, and that's exactly what we've seen over the last two quarters. A very sharp decline in business investment.

The one-month Libor [London interbank offered rate] spread is a measure of stress in bank lending. It's really, do you trust a bank to hold your money for a month. After that week, the stresses in the bank funding markets were huge. To us, that week, it looked very much like a run on the entire financial system. ( NB DON )

Nason: We were afraid of a complete and utter collapse of the global financial system.( NB DON )

Swagel: Imagine if the Fortune 500, blue-chip companies, can't buy paper clips or meet their payroll. All the things these firms rely on money-market funds and commercial paper for. And it goes downhill from there. It starts with the big firms and then every firm in the nation.

Fromer: This was an extremely difficult communications challenge. It made it enormously difficult to sell the package to Congress and for them to sell it back home. They were angry when they came back from home after the election. They had seen the amount of money they were being asked to put into institutions, getting anecdotal information from small businesses and lending institutions, and the picture was, we've invested significantly in these institutions, and we're not seeing credit flow to consumers and small businesses.

The markets were volatile for quite some time, and people became desensitized to volatility in the markets. What people didn't understand, which was quite reasonable, was the credit markets, how credit is provided in this country. That's not a criticism; it's arcane to anybody without a certain educational background. It's an almost-impossible-to-explain set of circumstances.

Nason: People were getting used to seeing the stock market go up and down. We were trying to explain, "What's happening in the equity market is not really what we're worried about. We're worried about some other market that you've never seen and aren't familiar with," and people look at you like you're insane because you're asking for $700 billion and you can't provide anything besides a chart to show why it's important.

[Here's the chart, which shows how rapidly widening credit spreads reflect a seizure in the credit markets.]

People could appreciate the money-market mutual funds situation. There is $3.3 trillion of money invested in money-market mutual funds. A panic in these funds helped in terms of selling the importance of our message. And the commercial-paper market stress was important in communicating this as well. If that market collapses, you could have huge employers saying, I'm going to start laying people off. I'm going to start shutting plants down, I'm going to start defaulting on my bonds, and that's going to trigger bankruptcy( NB DON ). Those are the kinds of things you had to say, in the doomsday scenario, to convince people that this was critical to the system.

After [the first TARP vote] failed in the House [on September 29], then the equity markets finally responded. [The Dow Jones industrial average plunged 778 points.]

Fromer: It was clearly a response that forced a number of people to say, "OK, we get it now."

Swagel: Even after the legislation passed, stresses in bank funding still got worse. So we got what we needed; we were thinking about buying assets, but we needed to think more broadly.

Nason: There were two purposes at the time. This is a critically important point and something the current administration is suffering under. The dual purposes were financial system stability and provision of credit to the economy. People are not focused at all on the fact that the former is the primary reason we went up and asked for emergency authority. To derail a total breakdown of the financial markets and the global financial system. And we believe and hope that the confluence of programs put into place in a very short period of time actually did that.

The second part of it is, getting credit flowing into the economy. People seem to only focus on, "Why isn't this money being put into the economy?" That's important, of course, but you have to remember a significant portion of this money was there to be a buffer against future losses.

Swagel: To me, the stabilization of the financial markets is the salient accomplishment of the TARP and the actions of the Treasury in the fall. The normal playbook for dealing with a bank crisis is first, winnow out the banking sector so the zombie institutions don't clog up the credit channels and divert resources. As a society, I'm not sure we're going to do that. Next is stabilize, inject capital into the firms that are left so they're still viable. And No. 3 is do something about the balance sheets. Give certainty about the performance of the assets and the viability of the firms. I think we did No. 2, we stabilized the system. No. 3 is still the ongoing challenge.

Nason: The reason the TARP morphed from asset purchases to injecting capital is really quite practical. Asset purchases were taking longer than we had hoped, and it was more complicated with the vendors. Also, we needed to be in lockstep with our brethren around the world. The U.K., France, and Germany were prepared to guarantee the liabilities of the banking sector and were going to deploy capital into their banks.

Fromer: The folks in place right now clearly have the advantage of looking back at what we did and the conditions that existed when we did it. They're benefiting from experience. A number of them were part of the process going back to last summer.

Swagel: The job of the TARP has not been done, but the first step is done. In terms of the larger picture of what matters to families, we're still pretty far away from getting back to normal.

Nason: There are still valuation problems with a lot of the assets on bank balance sheets. Then we still have to deal with inevitable credit contraction.

Fromer: It's not conceivable to me that there's a TARP II. It's going to take time for these programs to stand up and operate and invoke full participation from all quarters. Given dynamics right now, I think it's unlikely there will be another TARP."

Friday, April 17, 2009

Many of the poor underwriting practices in the subprime market were also potentially unfair and deceptive to consumers.

TO BE NOTED: From the Fed:

"
Chairman Ben S. Bernanke

At the Federal Reserve System's Sixth Biennial Community Affairs Research Conference, Washington, D.C.

April 17, 2009

Financial Innovation and Consumer Protection

The concept of financial innovation, it seems, has fallen on hard times. Subprime mortgage loans, credit default swaps, structured investment vehicles, and other more-recently developed financial products have become emblematic of our present financial crisis. Indeed, innovation, once held up as the solution, is now more often than not perceived as the problem. I think that perception goes too far, and innovation, at its best, has been and will continue to be a tool for making our financial system more efficient and more inclusive. But, as we have seen only too clearly during the past two years, innovation that is inappropriately implemented can be positively harmful. In short, it would be unwise to try to stop financial innovation, but we must be more alert to its risks and the need to manage those risks properly.

My remarks today will focus on the consumer protection issues raised by financial innovation. First, though, I want to say how pleased I am to join you for the sixth biennial Federal Reserve System Community Affairs Research Conference. We all want to see our communities grow and thrive, especially those that have been traditionally underserved. But the people in this room know as well as anyone that, when it comes to consumer protection and community development, good intentions are not enough. Hard-won knowledge, as exemplified by the empirical work presented here during the past two days, is required. I applaud your diligent and tough-minded research in analyzing what works and what doesn't. Only with such knowledge can efforts to spread prosperity more widely become increasingly effective.

Sources of Financial Innovation
Where does financial innovation come from? In the United States in recent decades, three particularly important sources of innovation have been financial deregulation, public policies toward credit markets, and broader technological change. I'll talk briefly about each of these sources.

The process of financial deregulation began in earnest in the 1970s, a period when stringent regulations limited competition and the range of product offerings in the markets for consumer credit. For example, Regulation Q, which capped interest rates on deposits, hampered the ability of depository institutions to attract funding and thus to extend credit. Restrictions on branching were a particularly significant constraint, as they limited the size of the market that individual depository institutions could service and thus their scope to reduce costs through economies of scale.1 The lifting of these regulations, especially branching restrictions, allowed the development of national banking networks. With national networks, the fixed costs of product innovation could be spread over larger markets, making the development and marketing of new products more profitable.

Many public policy decisions have affected the evolution of financial products and lending practices. One particularly important example was the Community Reinvestment Act of 1977 (CRA), which induced lenders to find ways to extend credit and provide services in low- and moderate-income neighborhoods. Another important set of policies was the government's support for the development of secondary mortgage markets, particularly through the government-sponsored enterprises, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. Secondary mortgage markets were rudimentary and thin in the 1970s; indeed, the Federal Reserve's Flow of Funds accounts do not even record private securitization activity until the early 1980s. As secondary mortgage markets--an important innovation in themselves--grew, they gave lenders both greater access to funding and better ability to diversify, providing further impetus to expansion into new markets and new products.

On the technological front, advances in information technology made possible the low-cost collection, processing, and dissemination of household and business financial data, functions that were once highly localized and, by today's standards, inefficiently managed.2 As credit reporting advanced, models for credit scoring gradually emerged, allowing for ever-faster evaluation of creditworthiness, identification of prospective borrowers, and management of existing accounts.

All these developments had their positive aspects, including for people in low- and moderate-income communities. Prior to the introduction of the CRA, as you know, many of these communities had limited access to mortgages and other forms of consumer credit. Subsequent innovations in financial products and services, processes, and technology helped at least some underserved consumers more fully enter the financial mainstream, save money, invest, and build wealth, and homeownership rates rose significantly.

Yet with hindsight, we can see that something went wrong in recent years, as evidenced by the currently high rates of mortgage delinquency and foreclosure, especially in minority and lower-income neighborhoods. Indeed, we have come almost full circle, with credit availability increasingly restricted for low- and moderate-income borrowers. And the damage from this turn in the credit cycle--in terms of lost wealth, lost homes, and blemished credit histories--is likely to be long-lasting. One would be forgiven for concluding that the assumed benefits of financial innovation are not all they were cracked up to be.

A number of factors explain the recent credit boom and bust, including problems stemming from financial innovation. From a consumer protection point of view, a particular concern has been the sharp increase in the complexity of the financial products offered to consumers, complexity which has been a side effect of innovation but which also has in many cases been associated with reduced transparency and clarity in the products being offered. I will illustrate the issue in the context of some familiar forms of consumer credit: credit cards, mortgages, and overdraft protection.

Credit Cards, Mortgages, and Overdrafts: Some Instructive Examples
The credit card is an example of financial innovation driven by technological advance, including improvements in communications, data management, and credit scoring. When the first general-purpose credit card was issued in 1952, it represented a way to make small loans more quickly and at a lower cost than the closed-end installment loans offered by retailers and finance companies at the time. Moreover, this form of credit doubled as a means of payment. Card issuers benefited by spreading fixed costs over multiple advances of credit, over larger customer bases, across geographic areas, and among many merchants.3 From the consumer's perspective, credit cards provided convenience, facilitated recordkeeping, and offered security from loss (by theft, for example).4 Their use gradually expanded among American families, rising to 43 percent in 1983 and to 70 percent by 2007. Among lower-income families, usage increased from 11 percent in 1983 to 37 percent in 2007.5

Mortgage markets saw similar product innovations. For example, in the early 1990s, automated underwriting systems helped open new opportunities for underserved consumers to obtain traditional forms of mortgage credit. This innovation was followed by an expansion of lending to borrowers perceived to have high credit risk, which became known as the subprime market. Lenders developed new techniques for using credit information to determine underwriting standards, set interest rates, and manage their risks. As I have already mentioned, the ongoing growth and development of the secondary mortgage market reinforced the effect of these innovations, giving mortgage lenders greater access to the capital markets, lowering transaction costs, and spreading risk more broadly. Subprime lending rose dramatically from 5 percent of total mortgage originations in 1994 to about 20 percent in 2005 and 2006.6

Innovation thus laid the groundwork for the expansion of credit card and mortgage lending that has taken place over the past 15 years or so, as well as some other forms of credit like auto loans. However, while innovation often brought consumers improved access to credit, it also brought increased complexity and an array of choices that consumers have often found difficult to evaluate properly.

Take the case of credit cards. In the early days, a card may have allowed the user to make purchases or obtain cash advances, with a single, unchanging annual percentage rate, or APR, applied to each feature. Card fees were typically limited to an annual fee, a charge for cash advances, and perhaps fees for making a late payment or exceeding the credit limit. In contrast, today's more-complex products offer balance transfers and treat different classes of purchases and cash advances as different features, each with its own APR. In addition, interest rates adjust much more frequently than they once did, and the array of fees charged for various features, requirements, or services has grown.

More-complex plans may benefit some consumers; for example, pricing that varies according to consumers' credit risk and preferences for certain services may improve access to credit and allow for more-customized products. Growing complexity, however, has increased the probability that even the most diligent consumers will not understand or notice key terms that affect a plan's cost in important ways. When complexity reaches the point of reducing transparency, it impedes competition and leads consumers to make poor choices. And, in some cases, complexity simply serves to disguise practices that are unfair and deceptive.

Mortgage products have likewise become much more complex. Moreover, in recent years, the increased complexity has sometimes interacted with weakened incentives for good underwriting, to the detriment of the borrower. The practice of securitization, notwithstanding its benefits, appears to have been one source of the decline in underwriting standards during the recent episode. Depending on the terms of the sale, originators who sold mortgage loans passed much of the risk--including the risks of poor underwriting--on to investors. Compensation structures for originators also caused problems in some cases. For example, some incentive schemes linked originator revenue to particular loan features and to volume rather than to the quality of the loan. Complexity made the problem worse, as the wide array of specialized products made consumer choices more difficult. For example, some originators offered what were once niche products--such as interest-only mortgages or no-documentation loans--to a wider group of consumers. And, we have learned, loan features matter. Some studies of mortgage lending outcomes, after controlling for borrower characteristics, have found elevated levels of default associated with certain loan features, including adjustable rates and prepayment penalties, as well as with certain origination channels, including broker originations.7 Although these results are not conclusive, they suggest that complexity may diminish consumers' ability to identify products appropriate to their circumstances.

The vulnerabilities created by misaligned incentives and product complexity in the mortgage market were largely disguised so long as home prices continued to appreciate, allowing troubled borrowers to refinance or sell their properties. Once housing prices began to flatten and then decline, however, the problems became apparent. Mortgage delinquencies and foreclosure starts for subprime mortgages increased dramatically beginning in 2006 and spread to near-prime (alt-A) loans soon thereafter. By the fourth quarter of 2008, the percentages of loans 60 days past due, 90 days or more past due, and in foreclosure were at record highs.8

Credit cards and mortgages are not the only product classes for which innovation has been associated with increased complexity and reduced transparency. I will cite one more example: overdraft protection.

Historically, financial institutions used their discretion to determine whether to pay checks that would overdraw a consumer's account. In recent years, institutions automated that process with predetermined thresholds.

Although institutions usually charged the same amount when they paid an overdraft as when they returned the check unpaid, many consumers appreciated this service because it saved them from additional merchant fees and the embarrassment of a bounced check. However, technological innovations allowed institutions to extend the service, often without consumers' understanding or approval, to non-check transactions such as ATM withdrawals and debit card transactions. As a result, consumers who used their debit cards at point-of-sale terminals to make retail purchases, for instance, could inadvertently incur hundreds of dollars in overdraft fees for small purchases. In response to this problem, the Board last December proposed regulatory changes that would give consumers a meaningful choice regarding the payment of these kinds of overdraft fees, and we expect to issue a final rule later this year.

Protecting Consumers in an Era of Innovation and Complexity
In light of this experience, how should policymakers ensure that consumers are protected without stifling innovation that improves product choice and expands access to sustainable credit? The first line of defense undoubtedly is a well-informed consumer. The Federal Reserve System has a long-standing commitment to promoting financial literacy, and we devote considerable resources to helping consumers educate themselves about their financial options.9 Consumers who know what questions to ask are considerably better able to find the financial products and services that are right for them.

The capacity of any consumer, including the best informed, to make good choices among financial products is enhanced by clear and well-organized disclosures. The Board has a number of responsibilities and authorities with respect to consumer disclosures, responsibilities we take very seriously. In the past year or so, the Board has developed extensive new disclosures for a variety of financial products, most notably credit cards, and we are currently in the midst of a major overhaul of mortgage disclosures.

In designing new disclosures, we have increased our use of consumer testing. The process of exploring how consumers process information and come to understand--or sometimes misunderstand--important features of financial products has proven eye-opening. We have used what we learned from consumer testing to make our required disclosures better. For example, our recently released rules on credit card disclosures require certain key terms to be included in a conspicuous table provided at account opening; we took this route because our field testing indicated that consumers were often already familiar with and able to interpret such tables on applications and solicitations, but that they were unlikely to read densely written account agreements.

We have also learned from consumer testing, however, that not even the best disclosures are always adequate. According to our testing, some aspects of increasingly complex products simply cannot be adequately understood or evaluated by most consumers, no matter how clear the disclosure. In those cases, direct regulation, including the prohibition of certain practices, may be the only way to provide appropriate protections. An example that came up in our recent rulemaking was the allocation of payments by credit card issuers. As creditors began offering different interest rates for purchases, cash advances, and balance transfers, they were also able to increase their revenues through their policies for allocating consumer payments. For example, a consumer might be charged 12 percent on purchases but 20 percent for cash advances. Under the old rules, if the consumer made a payment greater than the minimum required payment, most creditors would apply the payment to the purchase balance, the portion with the lower rate, thus extending the period that the consumer would be paying the higher rate. Under these circumstances, the consumer is effectively prevented from paying off the cash advance balance unless the purchase balance is first paid in full.

In an attempt to help consumers understand this practice and its implications, the Federal Reserve Board twice designed model disclosures that were intended to inform consumers about payment allocation. But extensive testing indicated that, when asked to review and interpret our best attempts at clear disclosures, many consumers did not demonstrate an understanding of payment allocation practices sufficient to make informed decisions. In light of the apparent inadequacy of disclosures alone in this case, and because the methods of payment allocation used by creditors were clearly structured to produce the maximum cost to the consumer, last year we put rules in place that will limit the discretion of creditors to allocate consumers' payments made above the minimum amount required. We banned so-called double-cycle billing--in which a bank calculates interest based not only on the current balance, but also on the prior month's balance--on similar grounds; we found from testing that the complexity of this billing method served only to reduce transparency to the consumer without producing any reasonable benefit. These actions were part of the most comprehensive change to credit card regulations ever adopted by the Board.

Similar issues have arisen in the mortgage arena. Many of the poor underwriting practices in the subprime market were also potentially unfair and deceptive to consumers. For example, the failure to include an escrow account for homeowners' insurance and property taxes in many cases led borrowers to underestimate the costs of homeownership. In this case, allowing greater optionality--which we usually think of as a benefit--had the adverse effects of increasing complexity and reducing transparency. Restricting this practice was one of the new protections in the residential mortgage market that the Board established in a comprehensive set of rules released in July. Banning or limiting certain underwriting practices, which the new rules do for the entire mortgage market, also helps to address the incentive problems I discussed earlier. For institutions that we supervise, these incentive issues can also be addressed by requiring that lenders set up compensation plans for originators that induce behavior consistent with safety and soundness.

Where does all this leave us? It seems clear that the difficulty of managing financial innovation in the period leading up to the crisis was underestimated, and not just in the case of consumer lending. For example, complexity and lack of transparency have been a problem for certain innovative products aimed at investors, such as some structured credit products.

Conclusion
I don't think anyone wants to go back to the 1970s. Financial innovation has improved access to credit, reduced costs, and increased choice. We should not attempt to impose restrictions on credit providers so onerous that they prevent the development of new products and services in the future.

That said, the recent experience has shown some ways in which financial innovation can misfire. Regulation should not prevent innovation, rather it should ensure that innovations are sufficiently transparent and understandable to allow consumer choice to drive good market outcomes. We should be wary of complexity whose principal effect is to make the product or service more difficult to understand by its intended audience. Other questions about proposed innovations should be raised: For instance, how will the innovative product or practice perform under stressed financial conditions? What effects will the innovation have on the ability and willingness of the lender to make loans that are well underwritten and serve the needs of the borrower? These questions about innovation are relevant for safety-and-soundness supervision as well as for consumer protection.

In sum, the challenge faced by regulators is to strike the right balance: to strive for the highest standards of consumer protection without eliminating the beneficial effects of responsible innovation on consumer choice and access to credit. Our goal should be a financial system in which innovation leads to higher levels of economic welfare for people and communities at all income levels.


Footnotes

1. For a listing of these rules, see Dean F. Amel and Daniel G. Keane (1986), "State Laws Affecting Commercial Bank Branching, Multibank Holding Company Expansion and Interstate Banking," Issues in Bank Regulation, vol. 10, no. 2 (Autumn), pp.30-40. Research indicates that non-interest expenses, wages, and loan losses all declined following the lifting of branching restrictions leading to lower loan prices. Also, the lifting of geographic restrictions lead to larger and more diversified banking institutions. See Randall S. Kroszner and Philip E. Strahan (forthcoming), "Regulation and Deregulation of the U.S. Banking Industry: Causes, Consequences, and Implications for the Future," in Nancy Rose, ed., Economics of Regulation, NBER Conference Volume. Return to text

2. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (2007), Report to the Congress on Credit Scoring and Its Effects on the Availability and Affordability of Credit, (Washington: Board of Governors, August). Return to text

3. Dagobert L. Brito and Peter R. Hartley (1995), "Consumer Rationality and Credit Cards," Leaving the Board Journal of Political Economy, vol. 103 (April), pp. 400-33. Return to text

4. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve (2006), Report to the Congress on Practices of the Consumer Credit Industry in Soliciting and Extending Credit and their Effects on Consumer Debt and Insolvency (Washington: Board of Governors, June). Return to text

5. See note 4, Report to the Congress on Practices of the Consumer Credit Industry, table 6; and Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (2007), 2007 Survey of Consumer Finances, Board of Governors. Return to text

6. See Chris Mayer and Karen Pence (2008), "Subprime Mortgages: What, Where, and to Whom?" Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2008-29 (Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, June); and Inside Mortgage Finance (2007), The 2007 Mortgage Market Statistical Annual vol. 1; The Primary Market (Bethesda, Md.: Inside Mortgage Finance Publications). Return to text

7. Lei Ding, Roberto Quercia, Wei Li, and Janneke Ratcliffe (2008), "Risky Borrowers or Risky Mortgages: Disaggregating Effects Using Propensity Score Models," Leaving the Board Working Paper (Chapel Hill, N.C.: UNC Center for Community Capital). See also Elizabeth Laderman and Carolina Reid (2009), "CRA Lending During the Subprime Meltdown (470 KB PDF)," in Revisiting the CRA: Perspectives on the Future of the Community Reinvestment Act, pp. 115-33 (San Francisco: Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, February). Other studies do not find evidence of consistent harm from stemming from certain practices or products. See, for example, Morgan J. Rose (2008), "Predatory Lending Practices and Subprime Foreclosures: Distinguishing Impacts by Loan Category," Leaving the Board Journal of Economics and Business, vol. 60 (January-February), pp. 13-32; and Christopher L. Foote, Kristopher Gerardi, Lorenz Goette, and Paul S. Willen (2008), "Just the Facts: An Initial Analysis of Subprime's Role in the Housing Crisis," Leaving the Board Journal of Housing Economics, vol. 17 (December), pp. 291-305. Return to text

8. Mortgage Bankers Association (2009), National Delinquency Survey, MBA, March. Return to text

9. See, for instance, materials on the Consumer Information portion of the Federal Reserve's website. Return to text"

Wednesday, April 15, 2009

a public-private hybrid doesn’t work

TO BE NOTED: From Bloomberg:

"Fannie, Freddie Face Pressure to Revamp as U.S. Aid Increases

By Dawn Kopecki

April 15 (Bloomberg) -- Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac are under pressure from lawmakers to revamp their operations as the mortgage-finance companies tap more government money to survive.

Among the options under discussion are combining the companies, breaking them up or reshaping their missions.

“It’s highly unlikely that they would return to the way they used to be,” said Ira Jersey, the head of U.S. interest rate strategy at RBC Capital Markets in New York.

Regulators seized Fannie and Freddie in September amid a rise in mortgage delinquencies that led to a combined net loss of $108.8 billion last year at the companies, the largest sources of financing for new U.S. home loans. The Treasury Department has injected $59.8 billion in emergency funds into the companies, including $46 billion issued two weeks ago.

Executives at Washington-based Fannie have discussed internally the possibility of taking over McLean, Virginia-based Freddie’s operations, according to people familiar with the matter. A formal approach isn’t imminent, said the people, who asked not to be named because the discussions are private.

The Treasury has agreed to give the two government- sponsored enterprises, or GSEs, as much as $400 billion through Dec. 31. That agreement probably will need to be extended by Congress before year-end, said Karen Shaw Petrou, a managing partner of Federal Financial Analytics Inc., a Washington-based research firm.

‘New Structure’

“There will be a massive re-write of the GSEs into some new structure,” though probably not this year, Petrou said.

House Financial Services Committee Chairman Barney Frank, a Massachusetts Democrat, is exploring ways to separate the companies’ private and public missions, said Steve Adamske, a Frank spokesman.

A merger would be the quickest way for regulators to cut costs by reducing Fannie and Freddie’s combined 11,000-person workforce, shedding underperforming mortgage assets and reducing the bureaucracy of running two companies with identical functions, said Christopher Whalen, co-founder of Institutional Risk Analytics in Torrance, California.

Substantial movement toward a merger may not come quickly. James Lockhart, who oversees the companies as director of the Federal Housing Finance Agency, has said they will remain under government control until the housing market recovers, and the Obama administration has ordered Fannie and Freddie to focus on helping homeowners meet their mortgage payments.

Public Mission

“It’s got to happen; we’re not going to put them back the way they were,” Whalen said of a merger. “The only way we’re going to be able to manage them is if we squeeze every last ounce of savings out of the administrative side and just focus on trying to keep the loss number under control.”

Brian Faith, a Fannie spokesman, and Michael Cosgrove, a spokesman for Freddie, declined to comment on the possibility of a merger or other restructuring.

Fannie, created by the government in 1938, and Freddie, formed in 1970 to be a competitor, ensure that banks have cash available to make loans by buying mortgages or guaranteeing securities they help create from the debt. Together they own or guarantee about 56 percent of all U.S. home loans.

Freddie has received $44.6 billion in federal aid, about three times as much as Fannie. Freddie’s tab at the Treasury will cost it at least $4.6 billion in annual interest payments, almost triple what Fannie owes.

“With both of them as wards of the state, do you need two of them?” said Joshua Rosner, an analyst with Graham Fisher & Co. in New York.

Ousted Management

Lockhart’s agency put Fannie and Freddie under its control and forced out executives after examiners said the two may be at risk of failing, threatening further damage to the housing market.

Top management of the companies remains in flux. Freddie Chief Executive Officer David Moffett unexpectedly quit last month. Fannie CEO Herb Allison emerged this week as the leading candidate to run the $700 billion U.S. bank-rescue program, according to a person familiar with the matter.

Under Frank’s plan, a government trust fund would assume the companies’ responsibilities to subsidize rental housing and a remaining company would continue to do business in the private mortgage market, according to Adamske, the lawmaker’s spokesman. He said it’s too soon to say what the final structure would look like.

To make Frank’s proposal work, regulators may need to put one company into receivership, a process similar to bankruptcy, said Armando Falcon, who was Fannie and Freddie’s government supervisor from 1999 through mid-2005. The fastest way would be for “one to buy all the assets and assume all the liabilities of the other, place the rest of it into receivership and wind it down,” he said.

Home Loan Banks

The solution is to “break them up,” said Representative Spencer Bachus of Alabama, the top Republican on the House Financial Services Committee. “One possibility that I’ve looked at is letting the Federal Home Loan Banks take over some of their obligations and operations.”

The Federal Home Loan Banks are 12 government-chartered cooperatives that lend money for mortgages at below-market rates to their membership of more than 8,100 thrifts, commercial banks, insurance companies and credit unions.

Daniel Mudd, ousted as Fannie’s CEO after the government’s Sept. 6 takeover, said too much is being demanded of the companies, and that lawmakers should rethink the idea of shareholder-owned firms with public missions.

‘Robust’ Debate

“We need to have a robust policy debate,” Mudd, 50, said in an interview. “Do you want large companies to be focused exclusively on housing finance, albeit prone to produce the result -- just like we’ve seen recently -- that when the housing market goes down, there will be blood?”

Falcon, now an industry consultant at Canonbury Advisors in Alexandria, Virginia, said a public-private hybrid doesn’t work. He has advised other nations to avoid following the Fannie and Freddie example in developing their secondary mortgage markets, he said.

“There are just too many inherent risks in following the U.S. model,” he said. “All that has been proven out.”

To contact the reporter on this story: Dawn Kopecki in Washington at dkopecki@bloomberg.net."

Tuesday, April 14, 2009

market participants were no longer sure that the financial institutions they were dealing with would be rescued

TO BE NOTED: From AEI:

The Obama administration and Congress are now
filling in the details of a long-anticipated plan for
reorganizing and restructuring financial regulation.
It is no exaggeration to say that the proposal will
create what are essentially government-sponsored
enterprises (GSEs) like Fannie Mae and Freddie
Mac in every sector of the financial economy.
The principal elements of the administration’s
plan are these:
• Establishing a federal agency as the systemic
regulator of the financial system
• Giving that agency the authority to designate
“systemically important” financial institutions
and establish a special regulatory
structure for these firms
• Providing a mechanism for the government
to take control of financial institutions when
and if it decides that their failure will create
“systemic risk”
To be sure, there are differences between the
implicit government backing that Fannie and Freddie
exploited and a designation as a “systemically
important” firm, but in competitive terms, these differences
are minor. Designation as a systemically
important firm is, in effect, a certification by the
government that a firm is too big to fail—its failure,
in theory, will create systemic risk—and this status
will be seen in the markets as lowering its risk as
a borrower. Lower risk will translate into lower
Financial Services Outlook
1150 Seventeenth Street, N.W., Washington, D.C. 20036 202.862.5800 www.aei.org
Reinventing GSEs: Treasury’s Plan for
Financial Restructuring
By Peter J. Wallison
In late March—timed to impress the G20—the Obama administration revealed its plan for regulating and restructuring
the U.S. financial system. There were no surprises; its approach, presented by Treasury Secretary Timothy
Geithner, endorsed both a single powerful systemic regulator, with authority to designate and regulate “systemically
important” institutions in every financial sector, and a system for liquidating or bailing out financial firms that might
cause a systemic breakdown if they failed. Although presented as a way to prevent a repeat of the current financial
crisis, the proposals will, if implemented, seriously impair competitive conditions in all U.S. financial markets—
enhancing the power of large companies that are designated as systemically important and threatening the survival
of those that do not receive that endorsement. Underlying the plan is the erroneous belief—shattered by the catastrophic
condition of the heavily regulated banking sector—that regulation can prevent risk-taking and failure.
Although the plan could get through Congress if the financial industry remains inert and apathetic, the weakness
of the administration’s case suggests that it is vulnerable to determined opposition.
March/April 2009
Peter J. Wallison (pwallison@aei.org) is the Arthur F. Burns
Fellow in Financial Policy Studies at AEI.
Key points in this Outlook:
• A thorough analysis of the Obama administration’s
financial regulation proposal.
• Firms deemed “too big to fail” will receive
competitive advantages.
• A special resolution system will be a recipe
for repeated bailouts.
• The cases of AIG and Lehman do not provide
a rationale for the administration’s plans.
• A systemic risk regulator is not a seer.
• The financial world, largely silent about the
administration’s proposal, should speak up
about its flaws.
- 2 -
funding costs, exactly the advantage that allowed Fannie
and Freddie to drive all competition from their market.
Indeed, it may well be that the systemically important
firms will be more formidable competitors than Fannie and
Freddie, which were restricted by their charters from
expanding beyond their secondary market role. There is
no indication that systemically important firms will be
similarly restricted.
In light of the competitive danger that the administration’s
proposal creates for smaller firms, the lack of any
adverse reaction thus far in the financial services sector is
surprising. It is also surprising that the administration would
back a plan that will inevitably create more firms—rather
than fewer—that are too big to fail. It is not hard to understand
why the largest firms might not see the plan as a
threat; they might believe that the government support they
receive will be more helpful than harmful in the future. But
it is harder to understand why there seems to be so little
vocal opposition at this point from the many smaller firms—
insurance companies, securities firms, hedge funds, and
finance companies—that will be forced to face governmentaided
competition. Perhaps they believe that these changes
are inevitable. There is little else to explain the support for
the idea from such organizations as the U.S. Chamber of
Commerce and the Securities Industry and Financial
Markets Association—two organizations that are normally
skeptical about excessive regulation and object to the
government picking winners and losers. This Outlook will
review the administration’s plan in detail, show the weakness
of the administration’s argument, and outline why and
how it will make major changes in the structure of and competitive
conditions in the financial sector of the economy.
The Administration’s Plan
In congressional testimony on March 26, 2009, Secretary
Geithner described the major features of the administration’s
plan:
To ensure appropriate focus and accountability
for financial stability we need to establish a single
entity with responsibility for consolidated supervision
of systemically important firms. . . . That
means we must create higher standards for all
systemically important financial firms regardless of
whether they own a depository institution, to
account for the risk that the distress or failure of
such a firm could impose on the financial system and
the economy. . . .
[W]e must create a resolution regime that provides
authority to avoid the disorderly liquidation of
any nonbank financial firm whose disorderly liquidation
would have serious adverse consequences on
the financial system or the U.S. economy. . . .
Depending on the circumstances, the FDIC and the
Treasury would place the firm into conservatorship
with the aim of returning it to private hands or a
receivership that would manage the process of winding
down the firm.1
The last sentence makes clear that this is not simply a
proposal for winding down failed financial institutions in
an orderly way; instead, it contemplates a “conservatorship,”
which would allow the government to take control
of a failing company and restore it to financial health. This
approach complements the idea that systemically important
firms are too big to fail and creates the vehicle that
would actually prevent their failure. Underlying the plan,
of course, is the glaringly false assumption that regulation
can prevent excessive risk-taking and failure by financial
firms. One glance at the catastrophic condition of the
heavily regulated banking industry should convince anyone
who thinks about it objectively that regulation is
not the panacea its proponents suggest. The administration
has not yet decided what agency would be the systemic
regulator, and it has not formally named the agency that
would have the authority to take over and resolve or rescue
failing or failed nonbank financial firms. The Federal
Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) seems to be the
frontrunner for the resolution agency; the Federal Reserve
has been mentioned frequently as the likely systemic regulator,
2 but this raises serious policy issues.3
The Consequences of Designating Firms as
Systemically Important
The dangers to competition inherent in the administration’s
plan arise in two ways: direct benefits to firms that
offer products enhanced by the apparent financial soundness
of the firm that offers them, and indirect benefits
through a lower cost of funds for firms that are perceived to
be less risky than their competitors. In insurance, for example,
where the financial soundness of a company could
make a competitive difference, the companies that can
boast that they are too big to fail are likely to be more successful
in attracting customers than their smaller competitors.
Similarly, but more indirectly, firms that can boast that
they are systemically important and thus too big to fail
would—like Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac—appear less
risky as borrowers than firms that are not protected by the
government, and this will produce lower financing costs.
Eventually, these firms will be able to use their superior
financing opportunities to drive competition from their
markets. Overall, the systemically significant firms will
be subject to less market discipline, will be able to take
more risks than others, will grow larger in relation to
others in the same industry, and will gradually acquire
more and more of their less successful competitors. Eventually,
we will see a market much like the housing market
that Fannie and Freddie came to dominate, with a few
giant companies, chosen by the government, that have
pushed out all significant competition.
It is, of course, possible that the opposite could occur.
The companies that are designated as systemically significant
could face so much costly regulation that they
become less profitable than their competitors. Indeed,
some supporters of designating systemically significant
firms have argued that systemically important firms will
face such onerous regulation that no firm will want the
honor. But this seems unlikely. Yes, it is possible to regulate
systemically important companies so strictly that they are
not able to compete effectively with others, but such a
policy would be self-defeating. If regulation so impairs
the operations of systemically important companies that
they cannot carry on their businesses efficiently, that will
only mean they will have to be bailed out sooner. The failure
of companies under regulatory supervision is a serious
indictment of the regulator’s effectiveness, and regulators
try hard to avoid it. Regulatory forbearance—refusal to
step in and close failing institutions—is a product of this
tendency and one of the most significant causes of the
savings and loan (S&L) and banking crisis of the late
1980s and early 1990s. So pervasive was regulatory forbearance
for S&Ls and banks during that period that a
policy called “prompt corrective action” was written into
the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation Improvement
Act of 1991 (FDICIA), the tough banking legislation that
was supposed to prevent future widespread bank losses.
As discussed below, it has not worked as hoped. Regulatory
forbearance seems to continue. The twenty-one banks
that have been resolved by the FDIC over the past year
have averaged losses on assets of 24 percent,4 even though
prompt corrective action was intended to enable institutions
to be closed before they had suffered any losses. Contrary
to the notion that regulators could be tough on
systemically important firms, experience shows that they
try to help their regulated clients succeed.
The Administration’s Plan for Resolving
or Rescuing Failing Financial Firms
The extraordinary FDIC losses on failing banks should be
a warning to anyone who contemplates a nonbankruptcy
system for resolving failed or failing financial institutions.
In the few cases in which regulators will actually close
institutions under the administration’s plan, the losses
will be expensive for taxpayers. In most cases, however,
regulatory forbearance will ensure that excuses will be
found to rescue most financial firms, also at taxpayer
expense. A rescue not only avoids embarrassment for the
regulator but is also generally approved by Congress
because it saves jobs and avoids financial disruption. It can
be safely predicted, accordingly, that for the largest institutions—
those designated as systemically important—the
new resolution system will simply become a bailout system,
with the taxpayers handed the bill. The capital markets
understand this tendency on the part of regulators. That is
why the administration’s proposal for a special resolution
system for failing financial firms increases the likelihood
that the capital markets will see systemically important
firms as less likely than others to be allowed to fail, and
thus less risky as borrowers.
Secretary Geithner defended this portion of his plan by
suggesting that it is merely doing for nonbanks what the
FDIC already does for banks. This argument omits the key
reasons for FDIC’s resolution process—why it exists and
who pays for it. Commercial banks and other depository
institutions perform a special role in our economy. They
offer deposits that can be withdrawn on demand or used to
pay others through an instruction such as a check. If a
bank should fail, its depositors are immediately deprived of
the ready funds they expected to have available for such
things as meeting payroll obligations, buying food, or
paying rent. Because of fear that a bank will not be able to
pay in full on demand, banks are also at risk of “runs”—
panicky withdrawals of funds by depositors. Although runs
can be valuable and efficient market discipline for insolvent
banks, they can be frightening experiences for the
public and disruptive for the financial system. The unique
attribute of banks—that their liabilities (deposits) may be
withdrawn on demand—is the reason that banks, and
only banks, are capable of creating a systemic event if they
fail. If a bank cannot make its payments to other banks,
the others can also be in trouble, as can their customers.
That is systemic risk, but it is unlikely to be caused by
any other kind of financial institution because these
financial institutions—securities firms, hedge funds,
- 3 -
insurance companies, and others—tend to borrow for a
specific term or to borrow on a collateralized basis. Their
failures, then, do not cause any immediate cash losses to
their lenders or counterparties. Losses
occur, to be sure, but those who suffer them
do not lose the immediate access to cash
that they need to meet their current obligations.
It is for this reason that describing
the operations of these nondepository
institutions as “shadow banking” is so
misleading. It ignores entirely the essence
of banking—which is not simply lending—
and how it differs from other kinds of financial
activity.
Because of the unique effects that are
produced by bank failures, the Fed and the
FDIC have devised systems for reducing the
chances that banks will not have the cash to meet their
obligations. The Fed lends to healthy banks (or banks it
considers healthy) through what is called the discount
window—making cash available for withdrawals by
worried customers—and the FDIC will normally close
insolvent banks just before the weekend and open them
as healthy, functioning institutions on the following
Monday. In both cases, the fears of depositors are allayed
and runs seldom occur. Although Secretary Geithner is
correct that the administration’s plan would, in effect,
extend FDIC bank resolution processes to other financial
institutions, for the reasons outlined above, there is much
less reason to do so for financial institutions other than
banks. Indeed, as discussed below, if the market had been
functioning normally in September 2008, both AIG and
Lehman Brothers could have been allowed to fail without
severe market disruption.
There is also the question of funding. Funds from some
source are always required if a financial institution is either
resolved or rescued. The resolution of banks is paid for by
the premiums that banks pay for deposit insurance; only
depositors are protected, and then only up to $250,000.
Unless the idea is to create an industry-supported fund
of some kind for liquidations or bailouts, the Geithner
proposal will require the availability of taxpayer funds
for winding up or bailing out firms considered to be systemically
important. If the funding source is intended to
be the financial industry itself, it would have to entail a
very large tax. The funds used to bail out AIG alone are
four times the size of the FDIC fund for banks and S&Ls
when that fund was at its highest point—about $52 billion
in early 2007. If the financial industry were to be taxed in
some way to create such a fund, it would put all of these
firms—including the largest—at a competitive disadvantage
vis-à-vis foreign competitors and would, of course,
substantially raise consumer prices and
interest rates for financial services. The
24 percent loss rate that the FDIC has suffered
on failed banks during the past year
should provide some idea of what it will
cost the taxpayers to wind up or (more
likely) bail out failed or failing financial
institutions that the regulators flag as systemically
important. The taxpayers would
have to be called upon for most, if not all,
of the funds necessary for this purpose. So,
while it might be attractive to imagine the
FDIC resolving financial institutions of all
kinds the way it resolves failed or failing
banks, it opens the door for the use of taxpayer funds to
protect the regulators of all financial institutions against
charges that they failed to do their jobs properly.
Sometimes it is argued that bank holding companies
(BHCs) must be made subject to the same resolution
system as the banks themselves, but there is no apparent
reason why this should be true. The whole theory of
separating banks and BHCs is to be sure that BHCs could
fail without implicating or damaging the bank, and this
has happened frequently. If a holding company of any
kind fails, its subsidiaries can remain healthy, just as the
subsidiaries of a holding company can go into bankruptcy
without implicating the parent. If a holding company
with many subsidiaries regulated by different regulators
should go into bankruptcy, there is no apparent reason
why the subsidiaries cannot be sold off if they are healthy
and functioning, just as Lehman’s broker-dealer subsidiary
was sold to Barclays Bank immediately after Lehman
declared bankruptcy. If there is some conflict between
regulators, these—like conflicts between creditors—
would be resolved by the bankruptcy court. Moreover, if
the creditors, regulators, and stakeholders of a company
believe that it is still a viable entity, chapter 11 of the
Bankruptcy Code provides that the enterprise can continue
functioning as a “debtor in possession” and come
out of the proceeding as a slimmed-down and healthy
business. Several airlines that are functioning today went
through this process, and—ironically—some form of
prepackaged bankruptcy that will relieve the auto
companies of their burdensome obligations is one of
the options the administration is considering for that
industry. (Why bankruptcy is considered workable for the
- 4 -
Over time, the process
of saving some firms
from failure will
weaken all firms in the
financial sector. Weak
managements and bad
business models should
be allowed to fail.
- 5 -
auto companies but not financial companies is something
of a mystery.) In other words, even if it were likely
to be effective and efficient—which is doubtful—a special
resolution procedure for financial firms is unlikely to
achieve more than the bankruptcy laws now permit.
In addition to increasing the likelihood that systemically
important firms will be bailed out by the government,
the Geithner resolution plan will also raise doubts about
priorities among lenders, counterparties, shareholders, and
other stakeholders when a financial firm is resolved or
rescued under the government’s control, rather than in a
bankruptcy proceeding. In bankruptcy, a court decides
how to divide the remaining resources of the bankrupt
firm. Even in an FDIC resolution, insured depositors have
a preference. It is not clear who would get bailed out and
who would take losses under the administration’s plan.
In any event, the current bankruptcy system is regarded as
potentially “disorderly,” although why a resolution by a
government agency will be more orderly has not been
specified. In any event, it is likely that favored constituencies
will seek, and probably get, more of the available funds
in a windup or a bailout carried out by a government
agency than they would in a normal bankruptcy. Given
that bailouts are going to be much more likely than liquidations,
especially for systemically important firms, a special
government resolution or rescue process will also
undermine market discipline and promote more risktaking
in the financial sector. In bailouts, the creditors will
be saved in order to prevent a purported systemic breakdown,
reducing the risks that creditors believe they will be
taking in lending to systemically important firms. Over
time, the process of saving some firms from failure will
weaken all firms in the financial sector. Weak managements
and bad business models should be allowed to
fail. That makes room for better managements and better
business models to grow. Introducing a formal rescue
mechanism will only end up preserving bad managements
and bad business models that should have been allowed to
disappear while stunting or preventing the growth of their
better-managed rivals. Finally, as academic work has
shown again and again, regulation suppresses innovation
and competition and adds to consumer costs.
With all these deficiencies in the administration’s plan
for creating systemically important companies—together
with a special liquidation or bailout system as an alternative
to bankruptcy—it is useful to consider the administration’s
rationale for such an extraordinary change in
the financial sector’s structure and competitive conditions.
It appears, in this connection, that the administration is
resting its case on only two events—the failure of Lehman
Brothers and the rescue of AIG—as the reasons for
advancing its extraordinary plan. Both examples, as discussed
below, are inapposite. AIG should not have been
rescued—saving the taxpayers $200 billion—and
Lehman’s failure was not the disruptive incident that has
been portrayed in the media and elsewhere. Indeed, if the
market had been functioning normally when Lehman
failed, its failure, like Drexel Burnham Lambert’s in 1990,
would have caused little market disruption.
The Exaggerated Significance of AIG
and Lehman
Secretary Geithner has defended his proposal by arguing
that, if it had been in place, the rescue of AIG last fall
would have been more “orderly” and the failure of Lehman
Brothers would not have occurred. Both statements
might be true, but would that have been the correct policy
outcome? Recall that the underlying reason for the administration’s
plan to designate and specially regulate systemically
important firms is that the failure of any such
company would cause a systemic event—a breakdown in
the financial system and perhaps the economy as a
whole. Using this test, it is clear at this point that neither
AIG nor Lehman is an example of a large firm creating
systemic risk.
In a widely cited paper, John Taylor of Stanford University
concluded that the market meltdown and the
freeze in interbank lending that followed the Lehman and
AIG events in mid-September 2008 did not begin until
the Treasury and Fed proposed the initial Troubled Asset
Relief Program funding later in the same week, an action
that suggested (along with then–treasury secretary Henry
M. Paulson’s warnings of imminent doom) that financial
conditions were much worse than the markets had
thought.5 Taylor’s view, then, is that AIG and Lehman did
not have any causal relationship to the meltdown that
occurred later that week.
Since neither firm was a bank or other depository
institution, this is highly plausible. Few of their creditors
were expecting to be able to withdraw funds on demand to
meet payrolls or other immediate expenses, and later
events and data have cast doubt on whether the failure of
Lehman or AIG (if it had not been bailed out) would have
caused the losses many have claimed. Advocates of
broader regulation frequently state, and the media dutifully
repeat, that the financial institutions are now “interconnected”
in a way that they have not been in the past.
- 6 -
This idea reflects a misunderstanding of the functions
of financial institutions, all of which are intermediaries
in one form or another between sources of funds and users
of funds. In other words, they have always been interconnected
in order to perform their intermediary
functions. The right question is
whether they are now interconnected in a
way that makes them more vulnerable
to the failure of one or more institutions
than they have been in the past, and there
is no evidence of this. The sections below
strongly suggest that there was no need to
rescue AIG and that Lehman’s failure was
problematic only because the market was in
an unprecedentedly fragile and panicky
state in mid-September 2008.
AIG Should Have Been Sent to Bankruptcy.
AIG’s quarterly report on Form 10-Q for
the quarter ended June 30, 2008—the last
quarter before its bailout in September—
shows that the company had borrowed, or
had guaranteed subsidiary borrowings, in
the amount of approximately $160 billion,
of which approximately $45 billion was
due in less than one year.6 Very little of this
$45 billion was likely to be immediately
due and payable, and thus, unlike a bank’s
failure, AIG’s failure would not have created an immediate
cash loss to any significant group of lenders or counterparties.
Considering that the international financial markets
are more than $12 trillion, the $45 billion due within a
year would not have shaken the system. Although losses
would eventually have occurred to all those who had lent
money to AIG, they would have occurred over time and
been worked out in a normal bankruptcy proceeding, after
the sale of its profitable insurance subsidiaries.
Many of the media stories about AIG have focused on
the AIG Financial Products subsidiary and the obligations
that this group assumed through credit default swaps
(CDSs). However, it is highly questionable whether
there would have been a significant market reaction if AIG
had been allowed to default on its CDS obligations in September
2008. CDSs—although they are not insurance—
operate like insurance; they pay off when there is an actual
loss on the underlying obligation that is protected by the
CDS. It is much the same as when a homeowners’ insurance
company goes out of business before there has been a
fire or other loss to the home. In that case, the homeowner
must go out and find another insurance company, but
he has not lost anything except the premium he has paid.
If AIG had been allowed to default, there would have been
little if any near-term loss to the parties that had bought
protection; they would simply have been
required to go back into the CDS market
and buy new protection. The premiums for
the new protection might have been more
expensive than what they were paying
AIG, but even if that were true, many of
them had received collateral from AIG
that could have been sold in order to defray
the cost of the new protection.7 CDS contracts
normally require a party like AIG
that has sold protection to post collateral as
assurance to its counterparties that it can
meet its obligations when they come due.
This analysis is consistent with the
publicly known facts about AIG. In mid-
March, the names of some of the counterparties
that AIG had protected with CDS
became public. The largest of these counterparties
was Goldman Sachs. The obligation
to Goldman was reported as $12.9 billion; the
others named were Merrill Lynch ($6.8 billion),
Bank of America ($5.2 billion),
Citigroup ($2.3 billion), and Wachovia
($1.5 billion).8 Recall that the loss of CDS
coverage—the obligation in this case—is not an actual
cash loss or anything like it; it is only the loss of coverage
for a debt that is held by a protected party. For institutions
of this size, with the exception of Goldman, the loss of
AIG’s CDS protection would not have been problematic,
even if they had in fact already suffered losses on the
underlying obligations that AIG was protecting. Moreover,
when questioned about what it would have lost if
AIG had defaulted, Goldman said its losses would have
been “negligible.” This is entirely plausible. Its spokesman
cited both the collateral it had received from AIG under
the CDS contracts and the fact that it had hedged its AIG
risk by buying protection against AIG’s default from third
parties.9 Also, as noted above, Goldman only suffered the
loss of its CDS coverage, not a loss on the underlying debt
the CDS was supposed to cover. If Goldman, the largest
counterparty in AIG’s list, would not have suffered substantial
losses, then AIG’s default on its CDS contracts
would have had no serious consequences in the market.
This strongly suggests that Secretary Geithner’s effort to
justify the need for a systemic regulator is based on very
Financial firms have
always been
interconnected in order
to perform their
intermediary functions.
The right question is
whether they are now
interconnected in a way
that makes them more
vulnerable to the failure
of one or more
institutions than they
have been in the past,
and there is no
evidence of this.
- 7 -
weak or exaggerated data. AIG could have been put into
bankruptcy with no costs to the taxpayers. A systemic
regulator would have rescued AIG—just as the Fed did—
amounting to an unnecessary cost for U.S. taxpayers
and an unnecessary windfall for AIG’s counterparties. We
will probably never know why the Fed decided to bail
out AIG, but the most likely reason is that it simply panicked
at the market’s reaction to the Lehman failure.
Lehman’s Failure Did Not Cause a Systemic Event.
Despite John Taylor’s analysis, it is widely believed that
Lehman’s failure proves that a large company’s default,
especially when it is “interconnected” through CDSs, can
cause a systemic breakdown. For that reason, Secretary
Geithner contends, there should be some authority in the
government to seize such a firm and keep its
failure from affecting others. Even if we accept, contrary to
Taylor, that Lehman’s failure somehow precipitated the
market freeze that followed, it does not support the proposition
that, in a normal market, Lehman’s failure would
have caused a systemic breakdown. In fact, analyzed in
light of later events, it is evidence for the opposite conclusion.
First, after Lehman’s collapse, there is only one example
of any other organization encountering financial
difficulty because of Lehman’s default. That example is the
Reserve Fund, a money market mutual fund that held a
large amount of Lehman’s commercial paper at the time
Lehman defaulted. This caused the Reserve Fund to “break
the buck”—to fail to maintain its share price at exactly one
dollar—and it was rescued by the Treasury. The fact
that there were no other such cases, among money market
funds or elsewhere, demonstrates that the failure of
Lehman in a calmer and more normal market would not
have produced any significant knock-on effects. In addition,
when Lehman’s CDS obligations were resolved a
month after its bankruptcy, they were all resolved by
the exchange of only $5.2 billion among all the counterparties,
a minor sum in the financial markets and certainly
nothing that in and of itself would have caused a market
meltdown.10
So, what relationship did Lehman’s failure actually
have to the market crisis that followed? The problems that
were responsible for the crisis had actually begun more
than a year earlier, when investors lost confidence in the
quality of securities—particularly mortgage-backed securities
(MBS)—that had been rated AAA by rating agencies.
As a result, the entire market for asset-backed securities of
all kinds became nonfunctional, and these assets simply
could not be sold at anything but a distress price. Under
these circumstances, the stability and even the solvency of
most large financial institutions—banks and others that
held large portfolios of MBS and other asset-backed securities—
were in question.
In this market environment, Bear Stearns was rescued
through a Fed-assisted sale to JPMorgan Chase in March
2008. The rescue was not necessitated because failure
would have caused substantial losses to firms “interconnected”
with Bear, but because the failure of a large financial
institution in this fragile market environment would
have caused a further loss of confidence—by investors,
creditors, and counterparties—in the stability of other
financial institutions. This phenomenon is described in a
2003 article by George Kaufman and Kenneth Scott, who
write frequently on the subject of systemic risk. They point
out that when one company fails, investors and counterparties
look to see whether the risk exposure of their own
investments or counterparties is similar: “The more similar
the risk-exposure profile to that of the initial [failed company]
economically, politically, or otherwise, the greater is
the probability of loss and the more likely are the participants
to withdraw funds as soon as possible. The response
may induce liquidity and even more fundamental solvency
problems. This pattern may be referred to as a ‘common
shock’ or ‘reassessment shock’ effect and represents correlation
without direct causation.”11 In March 2008, such an
inquiry would have been very worrisome; virtually all the
large financial institutions around the world held the same
assets that drove Bear toward default.
Although the rescue of Bear temporarily calmed the
markets, it led to a form of moral hazard—the belief that
in the future governments would rescue all financial
institutions larger than Bear. Market participants simply
did not believe that Lehman, just such a firm, would not be
rescued. This expectation was shattered in September
2008 when Lehman was allowed to fail, leading to exactly
the kind of reappraisal of the financial health and safety
of other institutions described by Kaufman and Scott.
That is why the market froze at that point; market participants
were no longer sure that the financial institutions
they were dealing with would be rescued, and thus it was
necessary to examine the financial condition of their
counterparties much more carefully. For a period of time,
the world’s major banks would not even lend to one
another. So what happened after Lehman was not the
classic case of a large institution’s failure creating losses at
others—the kind of systemic risk that has stimulated the
administration’s effort to regulate systemically important
firms. It was caused by the weakness and fragility of the
- 8 -
financial system that began almost a year earlier, when
the quality of MBS and other asset-backed securities
was called into question and became
unmarketable. If Lehman should have
been bailed out, it was not because its failure
would have caused losses to others—
the reason for the designation of
systemically important firms—but because
the market was in an unprecedented
condition of weakness and fragility.
Thus, the two examples that Secretary
Geithner has used to push his plan are
inapposite. AIG should clearly have been
sent to bankruptcy court, and Lehman’s
failure was only important because it
caused market participants to reappraise
the risks of dealing with one another in an
unprecedented market environment—in
which almost every large financial institution
was already weak and possibly insolvent.
Regrettably, the administration is
using these two inapposite examples—its
only examples—to set in place an entirely
new, broader, and wholly unnecessary system
of regulation and resolution. In the
unlikely event that the worldwide financial markets in the
future were to again become fragile and fearful, it would be
far better to have an ad hoc response from the U.S. government
than to establish a vast new regulatory structure
today for an event that is a wildly remote possibility.
The Weak Case for Designating
Systemically Important Firms
Even if there were facts that made it sensible to designate
systemically important companies today and create a
special system of resolution for them, major questions
would still be unresolved.
How Would Systemically Important Firms Be Identified?
Even if a systemic event could be caused by the failure of a
systemically important firm, how would we identify such a
firm in advance? Secretary Geithner has cited numerous
criteria in addition to size, including reliance on shortterm
funding or whether it is a source of credit for households.
12 There are no examples of a large financial
institution’s failure actually causing a systemic event for
the simple reason that, in every case of a large bank’s failure,
it has been bailed out. When other kinds of financial
institutions have failed, no systemic disruption has
occurred. In theory, for the reasons outlined earlier, the
failure of a large bank could result in a systemic
breakdown, but on what basis would
nonbanks be designated as systemically
important? Experience provides no answer.
Making things tougher for the proponents
of the administration’s plan is the fact that
the only examples we have contradict their
assumptions. Not only have large nonbank
financial institutions such as Drexel Burnham
failed without causing a systemic
event, but the failure of quite small firms
have caused what some might consider
systemic events, even though no one would
have classified them as systemically important
in advance. For example, when two
tiny securities dealers—Bevill, Bresler and
ESM—failed in the mid-1980s, Paul Volcker,
then chairman of the Federal Reserve
Board, told Congress: “The failure of some
dealers operating at the periphery of the
market . . . did have severe repercussions
for some customers. The insolvency of a
number of thrift institutions was precipitated,
while other institutions involved in financing or
servicing the fringe dealers were placed in some jeopardy.
In our highly interrelated and interdependent financial
markets, these developments carried at least the seeds of
more widespread systemic problems.”13 This comment
provides an indication of how malleable the concept of
systemic risk can be. In another well-known case, the 1976
failure of Herstatt Bank, a small German bank, caused a
breakdown in the international payment system, although
Herstatt would not have been on anybody’s list of systemically
important institutions when it failed.14 What
the Herstatt case shows is that regulating systemically
important firms does not provide any assurance that
systemic risk will be avoided. It creates the dangers to
competition discussed above, suppresses innovation, and
raises costs, but it does not make the financial system
materially safer.
Anyway, Would Regulation Work? Even if we assume
that it is possible to determine in advance which firms will
cause systemic risk, would regulation prevent it? Although
this idea is central to the administration’s case, all the
evidence we have points the other way: regulation is simply
not effective in preventing risk-taking and failure. The
Regulation adds costs
and reduces
competition and
innovation. If it does
not produce outcomes
that are better than
market discipline—
and it certainly has not
when we compare
unregulated hedge
funds and regulated
banks—it should not be
imposed on industries in
which government
backing is not present.
- 9 -
evidence is too clear to be ignored. After the S&L debacle
in the late 1980s and early 1990s—a financial crisis in
which most of the S&L industry as well as almost 1,600
commercial banks failed—Congress adopted FDICIA.
At the time, this legislation was considered extremely
tough banking legislation—so much so that, in a speech to
a conference at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago in
1992, Alan Greenspan, then chairman of the Federal
Reserve Board, complained that the law created too many
restrictions on banks.15 Greenspan might have had it
right; sixteen years after the adoption of FDICIA, we
entered the worst U.S. banking crisis since the Depression,
and perhaps the worst of all time.
This does not say much for the effectiveness of regulation,
and it certainly does not provide a basis for believing
that if we were to extend safety-and-soundness regulation
beyond banks to other areas of the financial sector, we
would be doing anything to prevent another crisis in the
future. Indeed, there is significant evidence that regulation
introduces moral hazard and makes the failure or weakness
of regulated entities more likely. One example of this is the
contrast between hedge funds—unregulated as to safety
and soundness—and commercial banks, which are heavily
regulated for this purpose. Hedge funds have long been
targets for lawmakers looking for opportunities to impose
new regulations.16 Yet, the current crisis was caused by
regulated banks, not hedge funds, and although some
hedge funds have failed, no hedge funds have had to be
bailed out by the government because they might create
systemic risk. Moreover, hedge funds have performed
much better than regulated banks in protecting their
investors against losses. As Houman Shadab testified
recently before Congress: “Even throughout 2008, while
hedge funds have experienced the worst losses in their
entire history as an industry, they have still managed to
shield their investors’ wealth from the massive losses
experienced by mutual funds and the stock market more
generally. From January through October 2008, the U.S.
stock market lost 32 percent of its value while the average
hedge fund lost approximately 15.48 percent.”17 Bank
stocks, of course, have performed worse than the stock
market as a whole.
It is difficult, then, to escape the conclusion that regulation
would not achieve any of the objectives that the
administration has set out for it and that the motivation to
broaden regulation and extend it to other areas of the
financial economy is ideological, rather than based on facts,
evidence, or even experience. Regulation adds costs and
reduces competition and innovation. If it does not produce
outcomes that are better than market discipline—and it
certainly has not when we compare unregulated hedge
funds and regulated banks—it should not be imposed on
industries in which government backing is not present.
Finally, the proponents of systemic regulation argue
that the administration’s plan should be adopted because
we have already bailed out so many firms that it is impossible
to return to a world in which there is no systemic
regulation. In other words, the moral hazard already
created by the bailouts that have occurred justifies new
and broader regulation. The cat, as they say, is out of the
bag. Leaving aside the absurdity of the government getting
more power because it made errors in the use of the power
it had already been given, the trouble with this argument
is that it treats the current financial crisis as an event that
is likely to recur in the future. However, this crisis—
involving as it does all developed countries and virtually
all major financial institutions—is an unprecedented
event that has required unprecedented actions by the
government. To use the current crisis as a basis for a
major policy change like that which the administration
has proposed, it is necessary to believe that a worldwide
meltdown of financial institutions will be a routine event
in the future. But given the fact that nothing like this
has ever happened before, there is no reason to believe
that after the current crisis is over the financial markets
will continue to expect bailouts of large nonbank financial
institutions.
A useful analogy is the Fed’s current role in addressing
the problems of the financial sector. Because of the severity
of the crisis, the Fed has been working hand in glove
with the Treasury Department to provide funds for bank
rescues and bailouts. If the markets were to take this cooperation
as a precedent for the way the Fed will act in the
future, they could well conclude that the Fed is no longer
a truly independent central bank. However, most people
in the financial markets probably understand that the
Fed’s extraordinary actions today will not create precedents
for the future and that, when the current crisis is
over, the Fed will act to show its independence of the
Treasury, with its reputation for objectivity in its decisionmaking
undiminished.
The Fed and Treasury are well aware of this problem
and recently issued a joint statement pointing out that
“[a]ctions that the Federal Reserve takes, during this
period of unusual and exigent circumstances, in pursuit of
financial stability . . . must not constrain the exercise of
monetary policy.”18 In other words, the mere fact that
some extraordinary and unprecedented actions had to be
- 10 -
taken to deal with this crisis does not mean that everything
in our financial system has changed. The same is true
for the structure of the financial system itself. It should be
designed for what is likely to occur in the future, not for a
situation like the current unprecedented crisis.
Conclusion
The administration is attempting to build a case for a
wholesale restructuring of the financial markets on the
basis of two inapposite examples—AIG and Lehman. The
fundamental changes its plan entails—the establishment
of a powerful regulator with the authority to designate certain
firms as systemically important and a system for
resolving or rescuing financial institutions other than
banks—will seriously impair competition in the financial
sector and threaten to create large companies that are not
significantly different in their competitive effect from
Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. Up to now, there has been
little resistance from the financial sector, but the administration’s
case for this vast change in financial regulation
is so weak—and the result of implementing its plan so
troubling—that concerted financial industry opposition is
likely to develop.
Notes
1. Timothy F. Geithner, written testimony (Committee on
Financial Services, U.S. House of Representatives, March 26,
2009), available at www.house.gov/apps/list/hearing/financialsvcs_
dem/geithner032609.pdf (accessed April 8, 2009).
2. See Damian Paletta, “U.S. to Toughen Finance Rules,” Wall
Street Journal, March 16, 2009.
3. See, for example, Peter J. Wallison, “Risky Business: Casting
the Fed as a Systemic Risk Regulator,” Financial Services Outlook
(February 2009), available at www.aei.org/publication29439.
4. Calculation by the author, based on Federal Deposit Insurance
Corporation press releases and available upon request.
5. John B. Taylor, “The Financial Crisis and the Policy
Responses: An Empirical Analysis of What Went Wrong” (Working
Paper 14,631, National Bureau of Economic Research,
Cambridge, MA, January 2009), 25ff, available at www.nber.org/
papers/w14631 (accessed April 8, 2009).
6. American International Group, 10-Q filing, June 30, 2008,
95–101.
7. A full description of the operation of credit default swaps
appears in Peter J. Wallison, “Everything You Wanted to Know
about Credit Default Swaps—but Were Never Told,” Financial
Services Outlook (December 2008), available at www.aei.org/
publication29158.
8. Mary Williams Walsh, “A.I.G. Lists Banks It Paid with U.S.
Bailout Funds,” New York Times, March 16, 2009.
9. Peter Edmonston, “Goldman Insists It Would Have Lost
Little if A.I.G. Had Failed,” New York Times, March 21, 2009.
10. See Peter J. Wallison, “Everything You Wanted to Know
about Credit Default Swaps—but Were Never Told.”
11. George G. Kaufman and Kenneth Scott, “What Is
Systemic Risk and Do Regulators Retard or Contribute to It?”
The Independent Review 7, no. 3 (Winter 2003). Emphasis added.
12. Timothy F. Geithner, written testimony, March 26,
2009.
13. Paul A. Volcker, statement (Subcommittee on Telecommunications,
Consumer Protection and Finance, Committee on
Energy and Commerce, U.S. House of Representatives, June 26,
1985), 1–2.
14. George G. Kaufman and Kenneth Scott, “What Is
Systemic Risk and Do Regulators Retard or Contribute to It?”
11–12.
15. Alan Greenspan, remarks (Twenty-Eigth Annual Conference
on Bank Structure and Competition, Federal Reserve Bank
of Chicago, May 7, 1992), available at http://fraser.stlouisfed.org/
historicaldocs/ag92/download/27852/Greenspan_19920507.pdf
(accessed April 8, 2009).
16. See, for example, Senate Finance Committee, “Grassley
Seeks Multi-Agency Response on Lack of Hedge Fund Transparency,
Expresses Alarm at Risk to Pension-Holders,” news
release, October 16, 2006, available at www.senate.gov/~finance/
press/Gpress/2005/prg101606.pdf (accessed February 4, 2008).
17. Houman B. Shadab, testimony (Committee on Oversight
and Government Reform, U.S. House of Representatives,
November 15, 2008).
18. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System and U.S.
Department of the Treasury, “The Role of the Federal Reserve in Preserving
Financial and Monetary Stability,” news release, March 23,
2009, available at www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/monetary/
20090323b.htm (accessed April 2, 2009).