Showing posts with label Investment vs Speculation. Show all posts
Showing posts with label Investment vs Speculation. Show all posts

Monday, January 12, 2009

"for those who invest with prudence and an eye toward long-term values, the market need not be a Ponzi scheme. "

From the NY Times, a Value Investing View:

In October, Columbia University’s business school honored its most famous investing guru, Benjamin Graham, with a series of panel discussions loosely connected to the market crash, which was then accelerating. The panelists, of which I was one, had contributed to an updated version of Graham’s 1930s textbook, whose signature themes are caution, avoidance of speculation and — at all costs — the preservation of capital( HE'S THE MAN BEHIND THE MAN BEHIND THE MAN ). The day we met, the Dow Jones industrial average fell 350 points en route to one of its worst months ever.

J. Ezra Merkin, a Wall Street sage, noted philanthropist and professional money manager, seemed to embody more than any of the other panelists the fear that was gripping traders. When it was suggested that the government should stop intervening in markets and bailing out banks, Merkin rejoined that the system had cracked and desperately needed help( I AGREE ). As the world now knows, Merkin had entrusted close to $2 billion of his investors’ money to someone even less dependable than the Dow — that is, the accused Ponzi artist Bernard Madoff. I have no reason to think that Merkin, at the time, had any knowledge of the fraud that was soon to secure his 15 minutes of fame, but that afternoon at Columbia now seems pregnant with latent connections. Perhaps Madoff’s investors lost a greater percentage of their money, and lost it more suddenly, than the rest of us. But beyond these mere matters of degree, is there really any difference?

At least for investors of attenuated time horizons, there is not. Public-securities markets are a wondrous artifice precisely because they offer permanent capital to industry and short-term liquidity to investors. Think about it: a General Electric or a Google sells stock to the public and then retains the proceeds — the capital — indefinitely. Even if the companies earn a profit, by selling more light bulbs or Internet ads, they are under no obligation to pay out the gains in dividends. How, then, do the shareholders claim their reward? Why, by selling their stock to other investors, of course. This means that, in the short term at least, each investor is dependent on the willingness of other investors to hop on board. If other investors go away, prices (even of solvent companies) plummet, to devastating effect on those who sell( I AGREE ).

In a Ponzi scheme, there is no G.E. or Google underneath the pyramid( TRUE. THE PHRASE IS NOW BEING MISUSED FOR RHETORICAL EFFECT. ): only air. Outgoing investors are paid from the money put up by new ones. And the game for Madoff ended, as Ponzi schemes always do, when he ran out of suckers.

In theory, stocks and bonds are more valuable than air. But when investors get hooked on trading securities (as distinct from owning them)( ALSO INVESTMENT VS SPECULATION ), especially ones that are overvalued, they are courting disaster. In retrospect, this was true of the legions that invested in mortgage-backed securities and in the banks that owned them, not to mention the many other companies affected indirectly. Nobody was thinking about what these companies were worth, only about the next quotation on the screen.

This was doubly true for the banks that held those wearily complex and difficult-to-value mortgage bonds. Look at the post-mortem issued by UBS, one of the world’s largest banks, which has suffered mortgage-related losses of some $50 billion (enough to bail out the auto industry several times over). Discussing one particular write down, the bank admitted, “The super senior notes were always treated as trading book (i.e., the book for assets intended for resale in the short term), notwithstanding the fact that there does not appear to have been a liquid secondary market( NEGLIGENCE AND FIDUCIARY MISMANAGEMENT ).” Legally, UBS was a bank; conceptually, it was investing with Bernie Madoff( TRUE ).

There is, of course, an alternative to this madness. Which is to invest for the long term, independent of the market action on any given day or year. This is what most small investors pretended, and maybe believed, they were actually doing.

Robert Barbera, the chief economist at ITG, an investment firm, says there are really three schools of investing. There are people who think they can identify superior stocks and bonds over the long term and selectively invest in those that they deem to be undervalued. Second, there are people who recognize that they don’t have this ability and resolve to salt away a fixed portion of their savings, month after month, in a generic and diversified portfolio. Though the first approach requires considerably more talent and is not recommended for novices, both should work.

What does not work is believing you are following either strategy No. 1 or 2 when you are actually engaging in the third approach — which is, essentially, following the crowd, day by day and hour by hour. At the top of the market, investors told themselves they were disciplined and in for the long haul. Now they are selling or refraining from investing. Some misjudged their liquidity needs and have come under pressure to raise cash; others have simply lost heart. Either way, they are dependent on new money to come in for them to get out.

Benjamin Graham’s premise (which he did not abandon, even in the depths of the Great Depression) was that, sooner or later, markets will reflect underlying corporate values( TRUE. ). Thus, he wrote, long-term investors had a “basic advantage” over others, because they could ride out bubbles and crashes rather than be gulled during such highs and lows into, respectively, buying or selling. In other words, for those who invest with prudence and an eye toward long-term values, the market need not be a Ponzi scheme( TRUE ). While stocks periodically go for roller-coaster rides, the earning power of the U.S. economy, albeit with serious fluctuations, endures( TRUE ). The people who chased unrealistic returns at the top, like those who are selling now, have simply cashiered their “advantage” to play a game that more nearly resembles Bernie Madoff’s.( I AGREE, ALTHOUGH SOME SPECULATION IS FINE, IF DONE CORRECTLY. IN OTHER WORDS, WITH FUNDS THAT YOU CAN AFFORD TO LOSE.)

Roger Lowenstein, an outside director of the Sequoia Fund, is a contributing writer for the magazine. His most recent book is “While America Aged.”

Wednesday, January 7, 2009

Am I the only one who doesn't see what’s so terrible about taking out fire insurance on your neighbour’s house

From Free Exchange:

"Not quite speculation
Posted by: The Economist l LONDON
Categories: Financial markets
LET me just add a comment to my colleague's post on speculation (below) in which she writes:


Am I the only one who doesn't see what’s so terrible about taking out fire insurance on your neighbour’s house( IT DOESN'T HELP REBUILD THE HOUSE. WHAT YOU'RE DESCRIBING IS NOT INSURANCE, BUT A BET ON THE HOUSE BURNING DOWN. ONE IS INTENDED TO PROTECT AN INVESTMENT, THE OTHER IS AN, ADMITTEDLY USEFUL, WAGER OR SPECULATION. IF TWO INVESTMENTS ARE INTENDED TO ACCOMPLISH DIFFERENT OBJECTIVES, THEN THEY ARE DIFFERENT. THE WAGER IS AKIN TO META-INSURANCE, AN ABSTRACTION BASED ON THE PURELY FINANCIAL ASPECTS OF THE HOME INSURANCE TRANSACTION. SINCE WE CAN SEE THE DIFFERENCE, THEN THERE IS ONE. I'M ON YOUR SIDE, BUT THERE IS A DIFFERENCE, AND THAT ALLOWS SOME PEOPLE TO SEE THE WAGER AS UNPRODUCTIVE. IN OTHER WORDS, THE MONEY COULD BE BETTER SPENT. OF COURSE, THAT'S A MATTER OF OPINION. ) (assuming it doesn't compel you to commit arson)? Even if you don’t own your neighbours home, you might anticipate that a burned out, abandoned house next to your own would lower the value of your property. True, there is something mean-spirited about profiting from a neighbour's misfortune, but that's not worthy of outrage. After all, these are financial markets, not primary school.
Even if you don't own the security you bet against, you might hold other investments positively correlated to it. Or, what’s wrong with buying a swap on a security whose fall in value poses systemic financial risk? That swap allows you to insure against a fall in your wages or most of your other assets.
There's nothing wrong with these practices, in my opinion, but they don't seem to quite make her point, which is that society seems to think there's something nasty about betting against a company for something other than a hedge. These examples reflect trades meant to hedge risk.( I'M FINE WITH HEDGING, AND EVEN SPECULATION, BUT THEY ARE OFTEN NOT INVESTMENT. )

But as she does go on to note, there are good reasons to allow people to speculate for speculation's sake (though tighter rules may be warranted, given behavioural inclinations toward, you know, frothiness). Bets made for profit provide crucial information to markets( TRUE ). If everybody on the street is insuring one guy's house, it may be because they think his house is in danger of burning down. This should be a pretty strong signal to the neighbour in question that his barbecue pit is too close to his porch (or some such thing). A financial derivative that improves the flow of capital, perhaps by providing the marketplace with better information, is worth having, even if some people make money buying and selling it for profit."

I've already agreed with these points, especially in defending the uses of CGSs and CDOs. However, they are often not investments:

“An investment operation is one which, upon through analysis, promises safety of principal and a satisfactory return. Operations not meeting these requirements are speculative( I AGREE ).””

That’s a quote from legendary value investor Benjamin Graham and it features prominently in James Montier’s first strategy piece of 2009."

Now, you're free to disagree with me, but that's how I feel. I have also defended Hedge Funds and hedging, and, it is true, hedging could be an investment strategy. However, as commonly practiced, I see it as speculation.

This is not a scientific or logical distinction. It is more like an art or a craft.

Tuesday, January 6, 2009

"Bernanke is making a time-inconsistent promise to hold interest rates low for an extended period."

From Alphaville:

"Battle of the bears

“An investment operation is one which, upon through analysis, promises safety of principal and a satisfactory return. Operations not meeting these requirements are speculative( I AGREE ).””

That’s a quote from legendary value investor Benjamin Graham and it features prominently in James Montier’s first strategy piece of 2009.

Titled “Bonds - speculation not investment”, the SocGen strategist reveals he has fallen out with colleague and uber bear Albert Edwards for the first time in eight years.

The reason for the row is, as you might have guessed, about the current state of the government bond market.

From my perspective as a long-term value-orientated investor, bonds simply don’t offer any value. They already price in the US slipping into Japanese-style prolonged deflation. However, they offer no protection at all if (and it may be a big if) the Fed can succeed in reintroducing inflation (what Keynes described as the “euthanasia of the rentier”). There may be a ‘speculative’ case for continuing to hold bonds, but there isn’t an investment case.( I AGREE )

To my mind, in principle, government bond valuation is relatively simple. I see the value as the summation of three components: the real yield, expected inflation, and an inflation risk premium. The market tells us the real yield for ten-year US government bonds is around 2%. Given that the nominal yield is also around 2% at the moment, the market is implying that inflation will be around 0% p.a. over the next ten years.( SILLY )

As regular readers will know Mr Edwards thinks differently. This from his final note of 2008.

John Kemp, a Reuters columnist wrote an interesting article yesterday entitled “Fed unleashes greatest bubble of all”. He stated, “Bernanke is making a time-inconsistent promise( THIS MIGHT BE WHY HE'S NOT CALLING HIS POLICY QUANTITATIVE EASING, WHICH WOULD DEFINITELY BE A TIME-INCONSISTENT PROMISE, AND SO HE'S AVOIDED THAT BY NOT TARGETING AN INFLATION RATE, HOPING TO KEEP THEM DOWN. IT'S ALSO A WAY TO GIVE A SIGNAL TO INVESTORS THAT INFLATION COULD BE AHEAD, WITHOUT CAUSING A PANIC TO SELL TREASURIES. ) to hold interest rates low for an extended period.” For if the policy is successful, investors buying bonds at current levels will incur “massive losses”.( TRUE ) I have been debating this very subject with my colleague James Montier recently. After all how much lower can bond yields go (see chart below)? But for now I retain my bias towards government bonds. Investors, I believe, underestimate how very close the global economy is to getting trapped in outright deflation( COULD BE ). We expect panic( I DON'T ) to grip the markets at some point in the first half of next year, sending both equity prices and bond yields substantially lower.( THAT'S WHAT COULD HAPPEN )

In fact, Montier says the divide between himself and Edwards is not as wide as it first might seem. He says both men could be right just at different times.
I tend to view the world through the lens of a long-term valueorientated absolute-return investor. Albert is often more willing to tolerate momentum driven shorter term positions (believe it or not!). Perhaps it is these differences in approach that have lead to us to adopt different positions on the merits of holding government bonds.

Of course, there maybe a speculative case for buying bonds. If the market is myopic (which is almost always is) then poor short-term economic data, and the arrival of outright deflation could easily see yields dragged even lower. Thus riding the news flow may be a perfectly sensible but nonetheless ‘speculative’ approach. However, I am an investor not a speculator (as I have proved myself to be appalling at the latter), thus government bonds have no place in my portfolio.

So what happens next? Montier says he does not have a clue. But he does have a nice a pay off line.

If the alternative scenario comes to pass and the Fed successfully reintroduces inflation (leading to what Keynes so vividly described as the ‘euthanasia of the rentier’2) then bonds look distinctly poor value, thus the risk is exceptionally high and skewed in one direction. As Jim Grant so elegantly put it government bonds may well end up being “return free risk” (as opposed to their more normal nomenclature of risk-free return). If yields were to rise from 2% to 4.5% investors would stand to suffer a capital loss of nearly 20%.

Return-free risk - marvelous!"