Showing posts with label Rajan. Show all posts
Showing posts with label Rajan. Show all posts

Tuesday, April 28, 2009

Needing to conserve capital and fearful that other firms might collapse soon, they largely stopped lending

TO BE NOTED: From the NY Times:

"April 29, 2009
Economic Scene
Time for Bank Creditors to Share the Pain?

The big debate about President Obama’s financial rescue plan has centered on whether he’s been right to avoid nationalizing the country’s biggest banks. But there is another, more pressing question about the plan that has received considerably less attention.

After the Federal Reserve’s stress tests identify the country’s sickest banks next week, who will bear responsibility for shoring up their balance sheets?

Will it be solely the government? Or will the government force institutions that lent money to sick banks in better times — their creditors — to take a hit by forgiving some of the loans?

Timothy F. Geithner, the Treasury secretary, and other officials are reluctant to force losses, often called haircuts, on banks. They worry that haircuts could create a cascade, in which some of the creditors that take losses become insolvent, while creditors of healthier banks begin wondering whether they will be subject to future haircuts. In the ensuing panic, financial markets could freeze up, as they did last fall.

But relying on the government alone to shore up the banks brings risks, too. In the long term, it could leave taxpayers with an enormous bill. In the short term, it could destroy the already thin political support for the rescue plan.

Recently — and, I’d argue, fortunately — the Obama administration seems to have become more open to the idea of encouraging loan forgiveness in certain situations. Beyond those situations, officials hope that no others are needed.

Yet that may turn out to be wishful thinking. The Treasury Department has only about $130 billion remaining in its Troubled Asset Relief Program, or TARP, fund. By comparison, American banks are probably facing an additional $1 trillion in losses over the next two years, the International Monetary Fund projects.

The gap between those numbers means that the debate over haircuts could be with us for a while.

The case against haircuts starts with Lehman Brothers. When Lehman collapsed into bankruptcy on the night of Sept. 14, its creditors were left with billions of dollars in loans to Lehman they would never recover. Needing to conserve capital and fearful that other firms might collapse soon, they largely stopped lending.

“That’s when this crisis took a quantum leap up in terms of seriousness,” as Janet Yellen, the president of the San Francisco Fed, recently said.

So imagine that on Monday, when releasing the results of its stress tests, the Fed says that several banks need more money to survive a deep recession. Assuming private investors are not willing to put it up, the government will then have two options.

It can increase the banks’ assets, by giving them more taxpayer money in exchange for an even greater ownership stake. Or the government can reduce the banks’ debts, by using its influence to encourage, or even demand, loan forgiveness.

Debt reduction, in exchange for an equity stake, is a standard strategy for dealing with failing companies. It’s what the Obama administration is trying to do with Chrysler’s and G.M.’s creditors. Under the tentative deal worked out on Tuesday, Chrysler’s creditors would receive about 28 cents in stock for every dollar of loans they forgave.

But banks aren’t like other companies. Like it or not, they are the heart of the credit system and thus the economy. No matter what happens to Chrysler’s creditors, Honda won’t stop making cars, and people won’t stop buying them. Imposing losses on Bank of America’s creditors, though, has the potential to freeze the financial markets.

One sign that such concerns are legitimate is the fact that they’re shared by some economists who saw the financial crisis coming well before Fed officials or Mr. Obama’s current advisers. At a Fed conference in 2005, Raghuram Rajan — then the director of research at the I.M.F. and now a University of Chicago professor — criticized Alan Greenspan for turning a blind eye to risk (and was in turn criticized by Lawrence H. Summers, now Mr. Obama’s lead economic adviser). Today, Mr. Rajan says that haircuts really do have the potential to make some financial firms insolvent and cause worldwide problems.

Yet he also says that the government should study whether it can sensibly impose any losses on creditors, rather than unquestioningly accepting Wall Street’s self-interested view that haircuts would be bad for the economy. “We constantly have to question the arguments the Street puts forward,” he said, “and ask whether they are really these holy cows who can’t be touched.”

Ever so gradually, the administration may be moving toward this more skeptical position.

In February, the Treasury began twisting the arms of some holders of Citigroup preferred stock to get them to convert it into common stock. (Preferred stock, despite its name, is something between a loan and stock.) The credit markets hiccupped, but quickly returned to their previous state. In the wake of the stress tests, the Fed and the administration may well push for more conversions along these lines.

The trickier issue is what to do with holders of so-called subordinate debt. In the spectrum of investments, subordinate debt is considered safer than preferred stock and tends to be subject to haircuts only when a company slides toward bankruptcy. Pushing a bank to the brink of bankruptcy would raise the specter of Lehman Brothers.

Now, some debtholders may be fearful enough of bankruptcy that they would willingly accept haircuts, figuring they are better than the alternative. On “Meet the Press” on April 19, Mr. Summers said one option for increasing the banks’ capital was “asset liability swaps,” by which he meant a voluntary exchange of loan forgiveness for equity.

The government’s main role would be to force existing equity holders to offer the swaps to creditors. Equity holders often oppose such swaps because their own stake is diluted. But government regulators could insist that the offer be made and then allow debtholders to accept or reject it. If the offer were, say, 60 cents on the dollar and the market price of the debt only 50 cents, the creditors might accept.

If steps like these, along with TARP, are enough to repair the financial system, haircuts won’t be needed. If not, the only remaining options will be more taxpayer money, more haircuts or both.

We already know what the bankers will say about haircuts, regardless of how carefully they’re devised: that they’ll end up hurting the rest of us. Remember, though, they said the same thing about stronger financial regulation, and they turned out to be spectacularly wrong. Stronger regulation would indeed have hurt many bankers. It would have benefited the rest of us.

This month, I interviewed Mr. Obama for a Q. and A. to be published Sunday in The New York Times Magazine, and I asked him why his economic inner circle was dominated by protégés of Robert Rubin. These protégés, like Mr. Geithner and Mr. Summers, are deeply thoughtful people, just as Mr. Rubin is. But in retrospect, they all gave too much deference to Wall Street.

Mr. Obama replied that his economic team also included people from outside the Rubin circle, which is certainly true. Still, Mr. Geithner and Mr. Summers remain the dominant forces in the team.

When they — and the president — consider Wall Street’s warnings about haircuts, I hope they also consider its track record. Lately, taxpayers haven’t done very well when they’ve listened to Wall Street’s advice.

E-mail: leonhardt@nytimes.com"

Wednesday, April 15, 2009

I would prefer uniform regulation to regulation that creates islands of regulation surrounded by uncharted oceans of the unregulated

From Free Exchange:

"Rajan roundtable: A response from the author
Posted by:
Raghuram Rajan l University of Chicago Booth School of Business
Categories:
Rajan roundtable

Raghuram Rajan is a professor at the University of Chicago Booth School of Business and a former chief economist of the IMF. His column on reforming the financial regulatory system sparked this dicussion, which can be followed in its entirety here.

FIRST, let me thank The Economist for hosting this debate and the many commentators who offered very useful thoughts on the ideas in my piece. Second, I would like to thank colleagues in the Squam Lake group (two of whom, Martin Baily and Hyun Shin, added their comments), with whom I have had enlightening exchanges on regulation. Finally, I should give credit to Mark Flannery of the University of Florida for first proposing the notion of contingent capital.

A short magazine page does not allow one to do full justice to the complexities of a problem. So if commentators rightly complain about my oversimplification of the issues, part of the blame lies with the space limitations in a magazine. But let me get to the comments. These fall into broadly three categories. Most commentators agree with the overall problem of pro-cyclical behaviour. Many express some concern about specific elements of the proposals. Finally, a few add their own suggestions.

On the overall diagnosis, the disagreements seem largely a matter of emphasis. These come from people who are either more sceptical of any regulation (Peter Wallison and some posts from Economist contributors) or from those who think the problem was deregulation driven by ideology (David Min). I agree that scepticism is the right initial stance, but given that we cannot promise not to bail out large firms in the future, and have indeed created substantial precedents for doing so, we have no option but to think of appropriate regulation. To do otherwise would be destructive of the free enterprise system that Mr Wallison cherishes, for it would entrench the power of large incumbent banks. While I sympathise with those who object to crude rules, I think Hyun Shin says it best when he argues that regulators rarely have the political or intellectual independence to exercise discretion, and “rules have a chance of success only when put in place at the outset, liberating the regulator to implement the consequences that flow from the rules”.

David Min rightly points out that the ideological cycle, which works on a longer timeframe than the usual business cycle, had a major role to play. But I would argue that the greatest danger is when the ideological cycle, reinforced by past deregulatory successes, merges with the business cycle. Indeed, overregulation in the bust plays into the hands of the ideologues, for the first attempts at eliminating senseless regulations, once the recovery takes hold, adds so much economic value that it further empowers the deregulatory camp. Eventually, though, the deregulatory momentum causes us to eliminate regulatory muscle rather than fat.

Turning to my specific proposals, start with contingent capital. Peter Wallison worries that it is an idea that “sounds good on first hearing but immediately collapses when subject to even limited analysis”. He makes some good points, but a moment’s reflection would suggest responses (which are contained in the more detailed analyses produced by the authors of the proposals) to his concerns. First, no one is proposing that levered financial institutions hold contingent capital claims on one another. That, as he and Annette Nazareth suggest, would be a disaster. It would, however, be simple to prohibit levered financial institutions (such as banks and insurance companies) from holding this class of claims, and easy to enforce such a prohibition. Who then would hold them? Typically unlevered institutions like mutual funds, pension funds, and sovereign wealth funds who like the added premium these kinds of instruments offer.

Would they hold these assets? We will not know until we try the proposals out. Yes, it would be painful for a mutual fund or a pension fund to suffer the loss. But on top of having obtained a substantial premium earlier on for taking the risk, as unlevered institutions they will also have the capacity to absorb the loss. More generally, these institutions hold equity, which is much riskier than the contingent capital proposed, both in normal times and in abnormal times. Equity has the advantage of being very liquid today, but if a sufficient amount of contingent capital is issued, it will become liquid also. Of course, if Wall Street protests too much against contingent capital, regulators can offer them the choice of issuing equivalent amounts of equity instead. I have little doubt which way financial firms will move, once their options are limited.

Some commentators object to the capital insurance proposal, arguing that insurers are likely to go broke precisely when banks are in trouble. The key therefore is for the insurance to be fully collateralised and hence fail-safe. Here is one way it could operate. Megabank would issue capital insurance bonds, say to sovereign wealth funds. It would invest the proceeds in Treasury bonds, which would then be placed in a custodial account in State Street Bank. Every quarter, Megabank would pay a pre-agreed insurance premium (contracted at the time the capital insurance bond is issued) which, together with the interest accumulated on the Treasury bonds held in the custodial account, would be paid to the sovereign fund. If the aggregate losses of the banking system exceed a certain pre-specified amount, Megabank would start getting a payout from the custodial account to bolster its capital. The sovereign wealth fund will now face losses on the principal it has invested, but on average, it will have been compensated by the insurance premium.

Turn finally to the closure proposal. Peter Wallison objects on grounds that the FDIC will not have the money to make good on the losses to depositors. I disagree. First, if the banks can be closed then they ought to be closed through prompt regulatory action way before the bank’s equity cushion, let alone its uninsured debt cushion, is fully eaten through. Second, a cursory study of past crises suggests that, typically, the longer regulators wait to close insolvent banks, the larger the eventual losses are to taxpayers. So I see quick closure as a benefit rather than a weakness.

Mark Thoma and a commentator from The Economist ask whether we will be able to ensure that such closure plans are serious. This is why regulators will have to stress test them periodically. Even if not perfect, the fact that banks have to produce the plans will force both banks and regulators to think about current weaknesses in legislation and regulation that prevent prompt closure, thus creating an impetus to remedy them. My sense is that if we set ourselves a goal to achieve weekend closure, automation, legislation, and organisational changes can get us a significant part of the way in a few years.

Martin Baily asks if we will impose too much of a tax on complexity with a closure plan. Perhaps! But I would rather we imposed a tax on (hopefully unnecessary) complexity than a tax on growth or variety. Alternatives like proposals to limit the size of financial institutions or to bring back Glass-Steagall-like separations would impose a far greater tax, and would be relatively ineffective to boot (see later).

Charles Goodhart raises the important point of cross-border operations. I am afraid that one outcome from this crisis may be that national authorities will insist that foreign banks conduct local operations through a separately incorporated local subsidiary. While this will impede efficiency, it could enhance stability and make closure easier. More generally, any bankruptcy plan will have to address knotty issues such as who has closure authority, what the loss-sharing arrangements between countries for closed banks will be, and how foreign operations of domestic banks will be treated. This is something that regulators have to pay far more attention to.

Finally, let me turn to alternatives. I was by no means suggesting that only these two regulations were needed, and that they could substitute for the whole host of regulations that are being contemplated. In particular, I am very sympathetic to the notion that compensation should be geared towards long-term performance, with bonuses paid out over time rather than immediately. I am also intrigued by Eugene Ludwig’s plea for greater reserving. Reserves are akin to the bank holding more capital, except that because reserves reduce profits and thus book capital, the capital does not really show up on the books so the bank cannot run it down by taking more risk. Similarly, the Geneva Report’s proposal of marking to funding deserves closer examination. I am not against countercyclical capital requirements, but I do not think they will be as effective as their fans suggest.

I find less compelling some of the more drastic regulatory measures that have been proposed. For instance, some have suggested that banks with insured deposits should not engage in trading for their own account, an activity known as proprietary trading. This would be a modern version of the 1933 Glass-Steagall act that separated commercial and investment banking in America. In addition to making the system more stable by pushing volatility-inducing activities away from areas that cannot be allowed to sustain losses, it might be argued that the separation is enforceable—because the lines are so clearly drawn, the public will know when they are being erased. Moreover, once in place, such separation will create pockets of rents that will generate defenders of the separation; the specialised proprietary traders will fight tooth and nail to prevent the commercial banks from encroaching on their turf. Finally, separation can create a variety of different players and strategies rather than a monolithic herd. This will lend stability to the system.

Yet these virtues may be more illusory than real. Glass-Steagall worked for a while only because there really was not much value to combining activities in the immediate post-Depression years. Over time, and long before the official repeal in 1999, it had been eroded in myriad ways. Not only are bright lines never so bright—for instance, how do you tell "illegitimate" proprietary trading from "legitimate" hedging—but also by standing in the way of private value creation, they generate enormous incentives to go around them. I would prefer uniform regulation to regulation that creates islands of regulation surrounded by uncharted oceans of the unregulated."

Me:

Don the libertarian Democrat wrote:
April 15, 2009 14:53

"I would prefer uniform regulation to regulation that creates islands of regulation surrounded by uncharted oceans of the unregulated."

This is a defensible position, but I agree with the notion of "regulate to purpose", and the following:

http://www.rgemonitor.com/us-monitor/255279/limited_purpose_banking_putt...

"With the government ready to absorb losses, banks are talking outrageous risks knowing that Uncle Sam will cover them if things go south. Raising the trivially low capital requirements of banks, as Paul Volker’s Group of Thirty Commission just proposed, won’t change this behavior.

What will change this behavior is to not let it happen. Banks should be allowed to initiate only conforming, i.e., government-approved, AAA-rated mortgages and business loans. These would be long-term, fixed-rate loans with 20 percent-down and payments below 25 percent of income. The government, via the Federal Financial Authority (FFA), would use tax records to verify loan payment-to-income ratios. It would also spot check collateral. Once approved, the banks would bundle and sell “their” loans within mutual funds."

My main reason for this is that we have a Lender Of Last Resort ( The Fed ) and a political system subject to lobbying and the fear of tough decisions in a crisis. Savvy investors know that the government will have to intervene in a financial crisis, no matter what it says. Also, the drift towards laxness in a time of prosperity is impossible to stop in our messy, interest driven, political system.

The uncharted oceans are necessary for financial innovation, and this dual system would do a better job of allowing that, in my opinion, than an over-arching system. This area should still be supervised and have to pay for its own insurance, but have zero government guarantees, for whatever worth their is in saying that. Moral hazard should be rigorously applied from the beginning, for even a modicum of effectiveness to stem from it. Again, Richard Bookstaber has some good ideas for risk evaluation in this sector.

Willem Buiter sums it up well:

http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/32 32

“Regulating the new financial sector

Willem Buiter
9 March 2009″

“Narrow banking vs. investment banking

The distinction between public utility banking/narrow banking vs. investment banking; (the rest) has to be re-introduced. I advocate a form of Glass-Steagall on steroids, with a heavily regulated and closely supervised narrow banking sector, engaged in commercial banking (taking deposits and making loans) and benefiting from lender of last resort and market maker of last resort support. The investment bank sector will also be regulated and supervised, but more lightly, and according to the same principles as other systemically important highly leveraged non-narrow bank institutions.

Universal banking has few if any efficiency advantages and many disadvantages. Economies of scale and scope in banking are soon exhausted. They tend to be fat to fail, have a lack of focus, and suffer from span-of-control negative synergies etc. Universal banks or financial supermarkets use their size to exploit market power and try to shelter their risky, non-narrow banking activities under the LLR and MMLR umbrella of the narrow bank that’s hiding somewhere inside the universal bank.
Penalise bank size

Splitting banks into public utility or narrow banks does not solve the problems of banks (narrow or investment) becoming too big or too interconnected to fail. It is therefore necessary to penalise bank size per se, to stop banks from becoming too large to fail (if they are interconnected but small, they are still not systemically important). I would penalise size through capital requirements that are progressive in size (as well as leverage).”

We need the underpinnings of our welfare state market system to be solid and sound. That's the system we actually have, and are going to have going forward for the indefinite future.