Showing posts with label Taleb. Show all posts
Showing posts with label Taleb. Show all posts

Wednesday, June 17, 2009

latest wager is more of a directional bet that regulators' efforts to prop up the financial sector and the broader economy will spark inflation.

TO BE NOTED: From the WSJ:

"
Black Swan Trader Bets Reputation on Inflation

Mark Spitznagel made a fortune predicting the "black swan" that hit markets last year. Now the relatively unknown hedge-fund manager is emerging from the shadow of his collaborator, Nassim Nicholas Taleb, with a big bet inflation will soar.

The 38-year old Mr. Spitznagel managed the Black Swan funds to triple digit returns last year with a bet on volatility. The returns have brought a flood of cash, sending assets for his firm, Universa Investments LP, rising to $6 billion from $300 million.

But, for all the gains, Mr. Spitznagel is still far less known than "Black Swan" author Mr. Taleb, who invests in the funds and helps shape their strategies but doesn't manage the money.

[Mark Spitznagel] Susan Hall

Mark Spitznagel sees economic stimulus efforts spurring inflation.

"Black swan" alludes to the once-widespread belief that all swans are white -- proved false when European explorers found black swans in Australia. A black-swan event is something extreme and highly unexpected.

Mr. Spitznagel's winning streak now will be tested. Universa is poised to make a huge wager that will reap big rewards if inflation surges. Inflation is on investors' radar thanks to extensive economic stimulus efforts.

"The consequences of the monetary bender the government has put on could( NB DON ) be huge," Mr. Spitznagel says.

The new fund, expected to start trading in July, will place bets on options tied to assets expected to benefit from a big leap in prices, including commodities such as corn and crude oil, and options on shares of oil drillers and gold miners. It also will short Treasury bonds, likely to weaken in an inflationary economy.

The inflation bet marks a change for Universa. Typically, Messrs. Spitznagel and Taleb don't have an opinion about the near-term direction of the markets or economy. Rather, they argue, investors tend to underestimate the risks of major market swings. The latest wager is more of a directional bet( NB DON ) that regulators' efforts to prop up the financial sector and the broader economy will spark inflation.

Mr. Spitznagel's approach to trading dates to his time as a fledgling pit trader in the early 1990s at the Chicago Board of Trade, where he bought and sold commodities such as cotton and soybeans.

Mr. Spitznagel's mentor, commodity-trading veteran Everett Klipp, trained him to limit losses by having him immediately exit trades as soon as they moved against him.

The notion of quickly folding a hand is alien to many traders who insist the market will come around to their point of view, says Mr. Klipp, 82, who retired several years ago. "You don't argue with the market," he said in an interview.

In the late 1990s, Mr. Spitznagel moved to New York to take courses at New York University, where Mr. Taleb taught. Mr. Taleb was planning to launch a hedge fund in which he would buy far out-of-the-money "put" options that would pay off if the market plunged sharply. Usually it didn't, and the options expired worthless, generating small losses. Options give their owner the right, but not the obligation, to buy or sell a stock at a certain price.

"One thing Mark taught me was that when someone isn't afraid of losing small amounts, they're almost invincible" because they have more staying power, Mr. Taleb said.

The strategy often either looses money or posts flat returns, which can turn off investors. Though the fund Mr. Taleb launched, Empirica Capital, initially made some money, when volatility fell its returns did, too. Burned out by the day-to-day trading grind, Mr. Taleb in 2004 closed down Empirica and concentrated on writing.

Mr. Spitznagel, meanwhile, joined a Morgan Stanley trading unit called Process Driven Trading. Not inclined to meet the bank's request that he sign a stringent "noncompete" agreement, he left Morgan in early 2007 and started to lay the groundwork for Universa.

Universa started trading out of a small office in Santa Monica, Calif., a location Mr. Spitznagel selected partly because of its distance from Wall Street. Mr. Spitznagel doesn't read financial news; rather, he developed software programs that troll options markets for deals.

A small group of mathematically trained traders track the programs, frequently discussing which trades to make with Mr. Spitznagel. Only 14 people work at the firm, though more will be hired for the inflation funds.

From time to time, a Chinese expert in tai chi visits the fund to train Mr. Spitznagel in the martial art, specifically the idea of using an opponent's force again him. Mr. Spitznagel sees similarities between the technique and his trading strategy, he says, since he believes the small losses he takes can eventually give him leverage over traders on the other side of his positions.

Mr. Spitznagel's strategy gained an advantage last year as the turmoil in subprime mortgages turned into a rout. In late September, he was meeting a client outside Chicago while keeping track of the market on his BlackBerry. Investors were on edge as Congress voted on the Treasury Department's $700 billion financial-rescue package.

Suddenly, the market plunged after the House voted it down. Mr. Spitznagel rushed back to his hotel to field calls from investors and manage the fund's positions from a laptop along with traders at Universa's headquarters.

During the next few months, Universa's positions surged in value. Investors piled in, eager for protection as the market spiraled lower. In early 2009, Mr. Spitznagel closed the strategy to new investors.

Now, Universa faces the risk that a quick market recovery eases investors' concerns about another crash. Mr. Spitznagel says that would be a mistake.

"People have been very quick to think that the low is in," he said. "They've lost all perspective on what a bear market can look like and how long it can last."

Write to Scott Patterson at scott.patterson@wsj.com"

Thursday, May 7, 2009

Equity investments are preferable to debt, a contributor to the current financial crisis, Taleb said.

TO BE NOTED: From Bloomberg:

"Global Crisis ‘Vastly Worse’ Than 1930s, Taleb Says (Update1)

By Shiyin Chen and Liza Lin

May 7 (Bloomberg) -- The current global crisis is “vastly worse” than the 1930s because financial systems and economies worldwide have become more interdependent, “Black Swan” author Nassim Nicholas Taleb said.

“This is the most difficult period of humanity that we’re going through today because governments have no control,” Taleb, 49, told a conference in Singapore today. “Navigating the world is much harder than in the 1930s.”

The International Monetary Fund last month slashed its world economic growth forecasts and said the global recession will be deeper than previously predicted as financial markets take longer to stabilize. Nouriel Roubini, 51, the New York University professor who predicted the crisis, told Bloomberg News yesterday that analysts expecting the U.S. economy to rebound in the third and fourth quarter were “too optimistic.”

“Certainly the rate of economic contraction is slowing down from the freefall of the last two quarters,” Roubini said. “We are going to have negative growth to the end of the year and next year the recovery is going to be weak.”

Federal Reserve Chairman Ben S. Bernanke told lawmakers May 5 that the central bank expects U.S. economic activity “to bottom out, then to turn up later this year.” Another shock to the financial system would undercut that forecast, he added.

‘Big Deflation’

The global economy is facing “big deflation,” though the risks of inflation are also increasing as governments print more money, Taleb told the conference organized by Bank of America- Merrill Lynch. Gold and copper may “rally massively” as a result, he added.

Taleb, a professor of risk engineering at New York University and adviser to Santa Monica, California-based Universa Investments LP, said the current global slump is the worst since the Great Depression that followed Wall Street’s 1929 crash.

The Great Depression saw an increase in global trade barriers and was only overcome after President Franklin D. Roosevelt’s New Deal policies helped revive the U.S. economy.

The world’s largest economy may need additional fiscal stimulus to emerge from its current recession, Kenneth Rogoff, former chief economist at the International Monetary Fund, told Bloomberg News yesterday.

“We’re going to get to the point where recovery is just not soaring and they’re going to do the same again,” he said. “We’re going to have a very slow recovery from here.”

Fiscal Stimulus

The U.S. economy plunged at a 6.1 percent annual pace in the first quarter, making this the worst recession in at least half a century. President Barack Obama signed a $787 billion stimulus plan into law in February that included increases in spending on infrastructure projects and a reduction in taxes.

Gold, copper and other assets “that China will like” are the best investment bets as currencies including the dollar and euro face pressures, Taleb said. The IMF expects the global economy to shrink 1.3 percent this year.

Gold, which jumped to a record $1,032.70 an ounce March 17, 2008, is up 3.6 percent this year. Copper for three-month delivery on the London Metal Exchange has surged 55 percent this year on speculation demand will rebound as the global economy recovers from its worst recession since World War II.

Commodity prices are also gaining amid signs that China’s 4 trillion yuan ($585 billion) stimulus package is beginning to work in Asia’s second-largest economy. Quarter-on-quarter growth improved significantly in the first three months of 2009, the Chinese central bank said yesterday, without giving figures.

Credit Derivatives

China will avoid a recession this year, though it will not be able to pull Asia out of its economic slump as the region still depends on U.S. demand, New York University’s Roubini said.

Equity investments are preferable to debt, a contributor to the current financial crisis, Taleb said. Deflation in an equity bubble will have smaller repercussions for the global financial system, he added.

“Debt pressurizes the system and it has to be replaced with equity,” he said. “Bonds appear stable but have a lot of hidden risks. Equity is volatile, but what you see is what you get.”

Currency and credit derivatives will cause additional losses for companies that hold more than $500 trillion of the securities worldwide, Templeton Asset Management Ltd.’s Mark Mobius told the same Singapore conference today.

“There are going to be more and more losses on the part of companies that have credit derivatives, those who have currency derivatives,” Mobius, who helps oversee $20 billion in emerging-market assets at Templeton, said at the conference. “This is something we’re going to have to watch very, very carefully.”

Taleb is best known for his book “The Black Swan: The Impact of the Highly Improbable.” The book, named after rare and unforeseen events known as “black swans,” was published in 2007, just before the collapse of the subprime market roiled global financial institutions.

To contact the reporters on this story: Chen Shiyin in Singapore at schen37@bloomberg.net; Liza Lin in Singapore at Llin15@bloomberg.net."

Tuesday, May 5, 2009

The solution for banks is relatively simple: just put a cap on their size

From Reuters:

"
Felix Salmon

a good kind of contagious

May 5th, 2009

The risks of consolidation

Posted by: Felix Salmon
Tags: economics,

I had a short chat with Nassim Taleb this morning about his new paper with Charles Tapiero, entitled “Too Big to Fail, Hidden Risks, and the Fallacy of Large Institutions”.

There’s a great deal of mathematics in the paper, which is full of equations and greek letters, but the gist of it is explained in pretty plain English:

Societe Generale lost close to $7 Billions dollars, around $6 Billions of which came mostly from the liquidations costs of the (hidden) positions of Jerome Kerviel, a rogue trader, in amounts around $65 Billions (mostly in equity indices). The liquidation caused the collapse of world markets by close to 12%. The losses of $7 Billion did not arise from the risks but from the loss aversion and the fact that costs rise disproportionately to the size of the bank…

Consider the following two idealized situations.

Situation 1: there are 10 banks with a possible rogue trader hiding 6.5 billions, and probability p for such an event for every bank over one year. The liquidation costs for $6.5 billion are negligible. There are expected to be 10 p such events but with total costs of no major consequence.

Situation 2: One large bank 10 times the size, similar to the more efficient Société Génerale, with the same probability p, a larger hidden position of $65 billion. It is expected that there will be p such events, but with $6.5 losses per event. Total expected losses are p $6.5 per time unit – lumpier but deeper and with a worse expectation.

In other words, small mistakes we can live with. Large mistakes we can’t, because when a mistake the size of Kerviel’s is unwound, the costs are enormous — not only to SocGen, which lost upwards of $6 billion, but also to all shareholders globally, who saw the value of their holdings marked down by trillions of dollars thanks to the effects of SocGen’s enormous and chaotic forced unwind.

The lessons here are broader, and apply to the practice of M&A more generally: when industries consolidate, there might well be economies of scale — but at the same time tail risks increase. What happens when a massive amount of technology outsourcing is consolidated in Bangalore, or computer-chip manufacture is consolidated in Taiwan? Efficiency rises — but so does the risk that one disastrous event could have massive systemic consequences.

The solution for banks is relatively simple: just put a cap on their size. (I’ve been suggesting $300 billion.) What’s the solution for other industries, which also naturally tend to consolidate and cluster? I’m not sure, but in an increasingly interconnected and just-in-time world, the risks are greater than ever."

Me:

There’s a good post on this at The Economics Of Contempt:

http://economicsofcontempt.blogspot.com/ 2009/05/too-big-to-fail-experts-on-make- them.html

He mentions the following post:

“Addressing TBTF by Shrinking Financial Institutions: An Initial Assessment Gary H. Stern President Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Ron Feldman Senior Vice President Supervision, Regulation and Credit Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis”

It’s a good and sensible post. Here’s one quote:

“On the first point, we anticipate that policymakers would face tremendous pressure to allow firms to grow large again after their initial breakup. The pressure might come because of the limited ability to resolve relatively large financial institution failures without selling their assets to other relatively large financial firms and thereby enlarging the latter. We would also anticipate firms’ stakeholders, who could gain from bailouts due to TBTF status, putting substantial pressure on government toward reconstitution. These stakeholders will likely point to the economic benefits of larger size, and those arguments have some heft. Current academic research finds potential scale benefits in all bank size groups, including the very largest.3 (Indeed, policymakers will have to consider the loss of scale benefits when they determine the net benefits of breaking up firms in the first place.)”

This makes sense to me, and even applies to the idea of taxing the size of banks, which I prefer. I prefer Narrow/Limiting Banking precisely because it’s harder to change politically. No doubt, there will be movements to change it. But we need a simple plan with simple rules. We’ve proven that we can’t handle complexity or lobbying or regulating very well.

An, yes, I bring this up just so that this plan will be considered. By the results so far, I’m not really the best person to advance this plan.

- Posted by Don the libertarian Democrat

that’s the Rubin trade: it works until it doesn’t

From Reuters:

"
Felix Salmon

a good kind of contagious

May 5th, 2009

Overconfidence and the financial crisis

Posted by: Felix Salmon
Tags: banking,

Malcom Gladwell kicked off this morning’s New Yorker summit with a talk about the causes of the financial crisis in general, and of the collapse of Bear Stearns in particular, and started provocatively, by saying that if his diagnosis of the problem is correct, then really “there aren’t any solutions”.

Gladwell’s diagnosis is simple: massive amounts of overconfidence, as revealed by its two most common symptoms, miscalibration and the illusion of control. Both of which can be seen in spades in the person of Jimmy Cayne, whose interviews with William Cohan for House of Cards show a man who’s really very deluded about what Cohan, and Cohan’s readers, are going to think of him.

More generally, said Gladwell,

What’s going on on Wall Street isn’t the result of experts failing to act as experts: it’s the result of experts acting exactly like experts act. It’s not a result of incompetence, it’s a result of overconfidence.

When we look for evidence of miscalibration in people, he said, we find it overwhelmingly in experts. We find it when people are in conditions of great stress and complexity and competitiveness. And we find it overwhelmingly with older, more experienced people, doing difficult things which they feel very strongly about.

Jimmy Cayne, said Gladwell, is the picture of overconfidence — and he’s quite typical when it comes to heads of Wall Street banks. And so, Gladwell concluded:

Our goal is not to enhance the expertise on Wall Street. Expertise they have in spades. Our goal is to rein in the expertise on Wall Street. Wall Street needs to be slower, less competitive, and a lot more boring.

This is undoubtedly true — the difficult thing, of course, is how to legislate it, in a world where banks are falling over themselves to repay TARP funds and start taking on lots of risk again. Here’s Matthew Richardson and Nouriel Roubini write in the WSJ this morning:

Consider also recent bank risk-taking. The media has recently reported that Citigroup and Bank of America were buying up some of the AAA-tranches of nonprime mortgage-backed securities. Didn’t the government provide insurance on portfolios of $300 billion and $118 billion on the very same stuff for Citi and BofA this past year? These securities are at the heart of the financial crisis and the core of the PPIP. If true, this is egregious behavior — and it’s incredible that there are no restrictions against it.

But if there were restrictions against this behavior in particular, the same banks, or other banks, would find other ways to chase risk, just because they’re so confident that they can make billions of dollars — and get themselves out of their present hole — by doing so. They might even be right: 95% of the time, they probably are right. But that’s the Rubin trade: it works until it doesn’t. And although it’s the easy solution to the problem, it’s also a very worrying solution to the problem, because it just sets up yet another inevitable meltdown at some unknown point in the future."

Me:

First, a quote from my teacher, Paul Feyerabend:

“Modern science, on the other hand, is not at all as difficult and as perfect as scientific propaganda wants us to believe. A subject such as medicine, or physics, or biology appears difficult only because it is taught badly, because the standard instructions are full of redundant material, and because they start too late in life. During the war, when the American Army needed physicians within a very short time, it was suddenly possible to reduce medical instruction to half a year (the corresponding instruction manuals have disappeared long ago, however. Science may be simplified during the war. In peacetime the prestige of science demands greater complication.) And how often does it not happen that the proud and conceited judgement of an expert is put in its proper place by a layman! Numerous inventors built ‘impossible’ machines. Lawyers show again and again that an expert does not know what he is talking about. Scientists, especially physicians, frequently come to different results so that it is up to the relatives of the sick person (or the inhabitants of a certain area) to decide by vote about the procedure to be adopted. How often is science improved, and turned into new directions by non-scientific influences! it is up to us, it is up to the citizens of a free society to either accept the chauvinism of science without contradiction or to overcome it by the counterforce of public action. Public action was used against science by the Communists in China in the fifties, and it was again used,, under very different circumstances, by some opponents of evolution in California in the seventies. Let us follow their example and let us free society from the strangling hold of an ideologically petrified science just as our ancestors freed us from the strangling hold of the One True Religion!”

Possibly because of him, I always ask questions like: Why did you need to use math? What are the assumptions of any theory or thinker? Are they exaggerating, lying, fudging,etc.? Is the expertise a skill, a position in a group, etc.?

One thing is very clear, which is that expertise is no guarantee of the ability to reason, write, explain, intuit, etc. If someone were to take the time to document basic fallacies of logic or misstatements of what certain theories say or what certain thinkers believed in the major press sources, it would be a full time job. Just look at the wonderful blog called Adam Smith’s Lost Legacy. I thought of doing a blog like this on Burke, but almost everything written about him is wrong or misleading.

As to our topic, I find these claims of complexity laughable. The expert should be able to explain to you the risks in very simple language. If he can’t, then say goodbye. When you read some of the explanations given for this risky behavior, they often violate common sense or basic reasoning. If you take a risky product, then divide it up into less risky and more risky within the risky product, it doesn’t magically make the risky product less risky.

I’m for Narrow/Limited Banking precisely because we need a foundation to the free market that everybody can understand.

- Posted by Don the libertarian Democrat

Monday, April 13, 2009

the bank will experience a run. To deal with this problem, we have deposit insurance

TO BE NOTED: From Derivative Dribble:

"
The Unbearable Lightness of Nassim Taleb In Uncategorized on April 13, 2009 at 7:30 am

Also published on the Atlantic Monthly’s Business Channel.

As Conor notes, Nassim Taleb offered up some less than sage advice in a recent “article” in the Financial Times. The article, which takes the form of a talismanic list, was crafted in order to the deliver humanity from its suffering by pointing our mind’s eye towards the failures of our regulatory dogma. Wielding powerful metaphors such as “Make an omelette with the broken eggs,” Taleb fails to meet even the lowest of standard for a statement on regulatory policy. “Counter-balance complexity with simplicity” might be an acceptable policy position for Deepak Chopra. But it is certainly unacceptable for an economist.

Looking beyond Taleb’s absurd delivery, the substance of his policies is, in large part, absent, and where present, addresses the real issues at play in a superficial and borderline whimsical fashion. It is unclear whether this is the product of haste, or the product of a complete lack of command over the issues and concepts. For example, Taleb states that:

7. Only Ponzi schemes should depend on confidence. Governments should never need to “restore confidence”. Cascading rumours are a product of complex systems. Governments cannot stop the rumours. Simply, we need to be in a position to shrug off rumours, be robust in the face of them.

To say that only Ponzi schemes depend on confidence — they don’t, since they’re the product of fraud and misrepresentation — is factually incorrect and suggests intellectual laziness. The extension of credit and contracting depend on confidence in the ability of a counterparty to perform. In a broader sense, the organizational structure of society depends on people being able to rely on the predictability of certain events around them (e.g., bus, train, and plane arrivals, banks maintaining deposits, etc.).

This organizational structure is itself a product of confidence. I am confident that the train will arrive shortly after I get to the train station in the morning, and as a result, I plan on taking the train to work each day. I am confident that my bank will maintain my deposit level, and so I don’t have a mattress full of cash. When confidence is eroded, the incentives of individuals become misaligned.

Take, for example, the case of a bank run. Each depositor has an incentive to withdraw its deposits based solely upon the assumption that all other depositors are doing so, since we have a fractional reserve banking system. Yet each would be better off if none of them withdrew their deposits. When the assumption rings true in the minds of enough depositors, that is, when confidence breaks down, the bank will experience a run. To deal with this problem, we have deposit insurance, which the Government provides to create and maintain confidence in the banking system."

Wednesday, April 8, 2009

Then we will see an economic life closer to our biological environment: smaller companies, richer ecology, no leverage

TO BE NOTED: From the FT:

"
Ten principles for a Black Swan-proof world

By Nassim Nicholas Taleb

Published: April 7 2009 20:02 | Last updated: April 7 2009 20:02

1. What is fragile should break early while it is still small. Nothing should ever become too big to fail. Evolution in economic life helps those with the maximum amount of hidden risks – and hence the most fragile – become the biggest.

2. No socialisation of losses and privatisation of gains. Whatever may need to be bailed out should be nationalised; whatever does not need a bail-out should be free, small and risk-bearing. We have managed to combine the worst of capitalism and socialism. In France in the 1980s, the socialists took over the banks. In the US in the 2000s, the banks took over the government. This is surreal.

3. People who were driving a school bus blindfolded (and crashed it) should never be given a new bus. The economics establishment (universities, regulators, central bankers, government officials, various organisations staffed with economists) lost its legitimacy with the failure of the system. It is irresponsible and foolish to put our trust in the ability of such experts to get us out of this mess. Instead, find the smart people whose hands are clean.

4. Do not let someone making an “incentive” bonus manage a nuclear plant – or your financial risks. Odds are he would cut every corner on safety to show “profits” while claiming to be “conservative”. Bonuses do not accommodate the hidden risks of blow-ups. It is the asymmetry of the bonus system that got us here. No incentives without disincentives: capitalism is about rewards and punishments, not just rewards.

5. Counter-balance complexity with simplicity. Complexity from globalisation and highly networked economic life needs to be countered by simplicity in financial products. The complex economy is already a form of leverage: the leverage of efficiency. Such systems survive thanks to slack and redundancy; adding debt produces wild and dangerous gyrations and leaves no room for error. Capitalism cannot avoid fads and bubbles: equity bubbles (as in 2000) have proved to be mild; debt bubbles are vicious.

6. Do not give children sticks of dynamite, even if they come with a warning . Complex derivatives need to be banned because nobody understands them and few are rational enough to know it. Citizens must be protected from themselves, from bankers selling them “hedging” products, and from gullible regulators who listen to economic theorists.

7. Only Ponzi schemes should depend on confidence. Governments should never need to “restore confidence”. Cascading rumours are a product of complex systems. Governments cannot stop the rumours. Simply, we need to be in a position to shrug off rumours, be robust in the face of them.

8. Do not give an addict more drugs if he has withdrawal pains. Using leverage to cure the problems of too much leverage is not homeopathy, it is denial. The debt crisis is not a temporary problem, it is a structural one. We need rehab.

9. Citizens should not depend on financial assets or fallible “expert” advice for their retirement. Economic life should be definancialised. We should learn not to use markets as storehouses of value: they do not harbour the certainties that normal citizens require. Citizens should experience anxiety about their own businesses (which they control), not their investments (which they do not control).

10. Make an omelette with the broken eggs. Finally, this crisis cannot be fixed with makeshift repairs, no more than a boat with a rotten hull can be fixed with ad-hoc patches. We need to rebuild the hull with new (stronger) materials; we will have to remake the system before it does so itself. Let us move voluntarily into Capitalism 2.0 by helping what needs to be broken break on its own, converting debt into equity, marginalising the economics and business school establishments, shutting down the “Nobel” in economics, banning leveraged buyouts, putting bankers where they belong, clawing back the bonuses of those who got us here, and teaching people to navigate a world with fewer certainties.

Then we will see an economic life closer to our biological environment: smaller companies, richer ecology, no leverage. A world in which entrepreneurs, not bankers, take the risks and companies are born and die every day without making the news.

In other words, a place more resistant to black swans.

The writer is a veteran trader, a distinguished professor at New York University’s Polytechnic Institute and the author of The Black Swan: The Impact of the Highly Improbable"

Thursday, April 2, 2009

increasing the amount spent on R&D and innovation does not lead to diversification and a reduction of uncertainty

From Business Week:

"
The Reverse Black Swan, Part I

Posted by: Michael Mandel on April 01

I recently reread The Black Swan and came to a surprising conclusion: Once I looked beneath the snarkiness, Nassim Nicholas Taleb’s book is brilliant—and I don’t use that term lightly. Yes, it is still true that Taleb is a confirmed pessimist and I am a confirmed technological optimist. But he’s gotten hold of fundamental truths which have changed some of my views about innovation and growth.

In particular, Taleb has a persuasive argument for why the economy, the financial markets and technology are fundamentally unpredictable in both directions—up and down—and why we should care.

Let’s start with the small reasons to like Taleb. First, he does a great job of nailing the bankers. He writes that the bankers:

are not conservative; just phenomenally skilled at self-deception by burying the possibility of a large, devastating loss under the rug.

(Remember that the book was published in 2007, before the crisis really took hold). In the same vein, Taleb writes that

people are often ashamed of losses, so they engage in strategies that produce very little volatility but contain the risk of a large loss—like collecting nickels in front of steamrollers.

Bingo—that’s exactly what the banks did.

But prescience about the crisis is not the only or even the most important reason to take Taleb seriously. His big innovation is that he has the best approach that I’ve seen for thinking about “fundamental unpredictability.”

The question of economic and technological unpredictability has been a top concern of mine for many years. In my 1996 book, The High Risk Society, I argued that “economic growth is disruptive and unpredictable”. In my 2000 book, The Coming Internet Depression, I stressed the increasingly violent nature of the lurches in the economy:

…the process of technological and business innovation amplifies the normal rhythms of the overall economy….The result is that the Old Economy business cycle has been replaced by the New Economy tech cycle: longer expansions, followed by deeper and harsher recessions.

Since then, I’ve repeatedly made the point that technological progress is fundamentally unpredictable (see here and here)

But Taleb has gone far beyond anything that I did—I’m envious and appreciative. His main point is that the world is consistently capable of generating “Black Swans”—outlier events which have an extreme impact, and “retrospective (though not prospective) predictability.” Obviously the current financial crisis is a Black Swan from the perspective of many people.

There are several important implications. First, Black Swans don’t have to be purely negative events—we can have positive or what I would call ‘reverse’ Black Swans as well. The invention of the Internet was a reverse Black Swan—unexpected, extreme impact, and inevitable in retrospect. More generally, the positive Black Swans are the technological innovations which could not have been anticipated ahead of time, and which work so well that we have experienced 200 years of rising living standards, despite the downward Malthusian pressure.

Taleb acknowledges the possibility of positive or reverse Black Swans, though he doesn’t spend much time on them. On the subject of technology, Taleb writes:

Prediction requires knowing about technologies that will be discovered in the future. But that very knowledge would almost automatically allow us to start developing those technologies right away. Ergo, we do not know what we will know.

As a result, going forward, we can view the world as able to produce unexpected positive technological innovations. There is no potential ceiling for growth. In addition, we could easily see a reverse Black Swan—a technological breakthrough that helps pull us out of the downturn.

However—and this is an enormous however—a Taleb-type analysis tells us something else. Because technological innovation really is fundamentally unpredictable, increasing the amount spent on R&D and innovation does not lead to diversification and a reduction of uncertainty. Taleb writes:

In spite of our progress and the growth in knowledge, or perhaps because of such progress and growth, the future will be increasingly less predictable.

This is especially true in the U.S. The way that the global economy developed in recent years, the U.S. has outsourced production to other countries, and kept the high-end task of design and innovation. As Taleb puts it:

The American economy has leveraged itself heavily on the idea generation.

This is precisely the point that I missed in my 2004 book, Rational Exuberance. In that book, I argued that a “hot” financial system—one with lots of highly mobile capital —would boost growth by seeking out and funding the development of the most promising innovations. I also argued that this growth-enhancing effect was worth the added possibility of financial crises. This is what I wrote then:

During boom times, the U.S. is able to fund innovative and growing new businesses with financial instruments--venture capital and junk bonds--that barely exist anywhere else. And then when the inevitable bust comes, the U.S. financial system is highly liquid and far more diversified than elsewhere, able to cope with sharp plunges without freezing up.

Har de har har. How stupid could I have been...

In my (weak) defense, I acknowledged in that book the possibility that the pace of innovation would slow, leading to lower real wages for college-educated workers. What's more, I pointed out that in the absence of innovation:

...it will become a lot harder to service all the debt that companies and people took on during the 1990s. Housing prices will slump and perhaps even plummet.

But despite this nod to the potential Black Swan of the financial crisis, I didn't really wrap my mind around the possibility that all this money out there might not get results. The fundamental unpredictability of technology means exactly that--we could summon up all this capital, and not get the big innovation. The big potential innovations such as biotech didn't take off in the post-2000 era, as was expected. As a result, that big pot of hungry money had no outlet except for housing. The innovations didn't happen.

What did happen was a big negative Black Swan--the financial crisis. And a Taleb-type analysis tells us that such negative unexpected events--a sudden acceleration of global warming, global war, a breakdown of the Internet, you name it--are almost guaranteed over a long enough time span.

So here's the thing. What reading Taleb tells me is that as a technological optimist, I need to accept three statements.

1) Unexpected technological breakthroughs are possible. That's good

2) The timing and nature of the breakthroughs cannot be controlled. That's bad

3) Unexpected large bad events are possible as well. That's bad. In fact, we can get bad events which have as big an impact, in the negative direction, as the technological innovations.

Whew. That's it for this post. In my next post on Taleb, I will talk about the implications of these three statements for financial and innovation policy."

Tuesday, March 10, 2009

We need to move beyond the fat-tail critiques and the ‘be careful’ mantra to discover and analyze them.

From Richard Bookstaber:

"The Fat-Tailed Straw Man

My Time article about the quant meltdown of August, 2007 started with “Looks like Wall Street’s mad scientists have blown up the lab again.” Articles on Wall Street’s mad scientist blowing up the lab seem to come out every month in one major publication or another. The New York Times has a story along these lines today and had a similar story in January.

There is a constant theme in these articles, invariably including a quote from Nassim Taleb, that quants generally, and quantitative risk managers specifically, missed the boat by thinking, despite all evidence to the contrary, that security returns can be modeled by a Normal distribution.

This is a straw man argument. It is an attack on something that no one believes.

Is there anyone well trained in quantitative methods working on Wall Street who does not know that security returns have fat tails? It is discussed in most every investment text book. Fat tails are apparent – even if we ignore periods of crisis – in daily return series. And historically, every year there is some market or other that has suffered a ten standard deviation move of the "where did that come from" variety. I am firmly in the camp of those who understand there are unanticipatable risks; as far back as an article I co-authored in 1985, I have argued for the need to recognize that we face uncertainty from the unforeseeable. To get an idea of how far back the appreciation of this sort of risk goes in economic thought, consider the fact that it is sometimes referred to as Knightian uncertainty.

Is there any risk manager who does not understand that VaR will not capture the risk of market crises and regime changes? The conventional VaR methods are based on historical data, and so will only be an accurate view of risk if tomorrow is drawn from the same population as the sample it uses. VaR is not perfect, it cannot do everything. But if we understand its flaws – and every professional risk manager does – then it is a useful guide for day-to-day market risk. If you want to add fat tails, fine. But as I will explain below, that is not the solution.

So, then, why is there so much currency given to a criticism of something that no one believes in the first place?

It is because quant methods sometimes fail. We can quibble with whether ‘sometimes’ should be replaced with ‘often’ or ‘frequently’ or ‘every now and again’, but we all know they are not perfect. We are not, after all, talking about physics, about timeless and universal laws of the universe when we deal with securities. Weird stuff happens. And the place where the imperfection is most telling is in risk management.

When the risk manager misses the equivalent of a force five hurricane, we ask what is wrong with his methods. By definition, what he missed was a ten or twenty standard deviation event, so we tell him he ignored fat tails. There you have it, you failed because you did not incorporate fat tails. This is tautological. If I miss a large risk – which will occur on occasion even if I am fully competent; that is why they are called risks – I will have failed to account for a fat tailed event. I can tell you that ahead of time. I can tell you now – as can everyone in risk management – that I will miss something. If after the fact you want to castigate me for not incorporating sufficiently fat tailed events, let the flogging begin.

I remember a cartoon that showed a man sitting behind a desk with a name plate that read ‘risk manager’. The man sitting in front of the desk said, “Be careful? That’s all you can tell me, is to be careful?” Observing that extreme events can occur in the markets is about as useful as saying “be careful”. We all know they will occur. And once they have occurred, we will all kick ourselves and our risk managers and our models, and ask “how could we have missed that?”

The flaw comes in the way we answer that question, a question that can be stated more analytically as “what are the dynamics of the market that we failed to incorporate.” If we answer by throwing our hands into the air and saying, “well, who knows, I guess that was one of them there ten standard deviation events”, or “what do you expect; that’s fat tails for you”, we will be in the same place when the next crisis arrives. If instead we build our models with fatter and fatter tailed distributions, so that after the event we can say, “see, what did I tell you, there was one of those fat tailed events that I postulated in my model”, or “see, I told you to be careful”, does that count for progress?

So, to recap, we all know that there are fat tails; it doesn’t do any good to state the mantra over and over again that securities do not follow a Normal distribution. Really, we all get it. We should be constructive in trying to move risk management beyond the point of simply noting that there are fat tails, beyond admonitions like “hey, you know, shit happens, so be careful.” And that means understanding the dynamics that create the fat tails, in particular, that lead to market crisis and unexpected linkages between markets.

What are these dynamics?

One of them, which I have written about repeatedly, is the liquidity crisis cycle. An exogenous shock occurs in a highly leveraged market, and the resulting forced selling leads to a cascading cycle downward in prices. This then propagates to other markets as those who need to liquidate find the market that is under pressure no longer can support their liquidity needs. Thus there is contagion based not on economic linkages, but based on who is under pressure and what else they are holding. This cycle evolves unrelated to historical relationships, out of the reach of VaR-types of models, but that does not mean it is beyond analysis.

Granted it is not easy to trace the risk of these potential liquidity crisis cycles. To do so with accuracy, we need to know the leverage and positions of the market participants. In my previous post, "Mapping the Market Genome", I argued that this should be the role of a market regulator. But even absent that level of detail, perhaps we can get some information indirectly from looking at market flows.

No doubt there are other dynamics that lead to the fat tailed events currently frustrating our efforts to manage risk in the face of market crises. We need to move beyond the fat-tail critiques and the ‘be careful’ mantra to discover and analyze them."

Me:

Don said...

"An exogenous shock occurs in a highly leveraged market, and the resulting forced selling leads to a cascading cycle downward in prices. This then propagates to other markets as those who need to liquidate find the market that is under pressure no longer can support their liquidity needs. Thus there is contagion based not on economic linkages, but based on who is under pressure and what else they are holding."

I look at this through a Fisher lens. It seems to me that one problem is that the leverage, while high, appears contained if it can be wound down in a contained manner, which it often is. What needs to be added is panic, which precludes an organized and efficient winding down, because its effects go outside of the immediate investment environment. So, while focusing on leverage and linkages seems like a good idea, panic, once started, is hard to predict or contain. So we need to ask if there is a way to preclude panic, in the way that FDIC insurance is used to preclude bank runs.

Truthfully speaking, following Bagehot, if there is a LOLR, it is going to be assumed to be a guarantor. Yet, ideas of insurance seem to be too expensive for banks or too little to cover losses.

The solution, to me, is to have a government guaranteed narrow/limited banking system, alongside a regulated/self-insured/non-guaranteed financial sector. Hopefully, because there is a LOLR, and a solid banking system under it, along with some insurance, perhaps bought from the government, that would be enough to stop a Calling Run breaking out system wide.

The problem with assessing risk is that it can vary. In one instance, it can be contained, in another, it can't.

As best as I can tell, VaR, CDSs, CDOs, have valid uses. In hearing calls for banning them or other investment instruments, we're involved in a kind of Debt-Deflation of human ability. We've gone from hubris to impotence and skipped the sensible middle. It doesn't seem to me to be a valid argument that, since we can't predict everything, we can't predict anything. There is also a difference between not seeing risk, and ignoring it. I think that our situation was caused by the latter.

Don the libertarian Democrat

March 10, 2009 11:51 PM

Don said...

Here's a post I came across today which says some of what I was trying to say, as a simple citizen:

"Modelling financial turmoil through endogenous risk"

http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node%2F3243

It begins:

"Financial crises are often accompanied by large price changes, but large price changes by themselves do not constitute a crisis. Public announcements of important macroeconomic statistics, such as the US employment report, are sometimes marked by large, discrete price changes at the time of announcement. However, such price changes are arguably the signs of a smoothly functioning market that is able to incorporate new information quickly. The market typically finds composure quite rapidly after such discrete price changes.
A crisis feeds on itself

In contrast, the distinguishing feature of crisis episodes is that they seem to gather momentum from the endogenous responses of the market participants themselves. Rather like a tropical storm over a warm sea, they gather more energy as they develop. As financial conditions worsen, the willingness of market participants to bear risk seemingly evaporates. They curtail their exposures and generally attempt to take on a more prudent, conservative stance.

However, the shedding of exposures results in negative spillovers on other market participants from the sale of assets or withdrawal of credit. As prices fall, measured risks rise, or previous correlations break down, market participants respond by further cutting exposures. The global financial crisis of 2007-9 has served as a live laboratory for many such distress episodes."

Don the libertarian Democrat

Rick Bookstaber said...

This point of endogenous responses is what I am talking about with the liquidity crisis cycle, discussed towards the end of the post.

In that cycle, what makes for the endogenous acceleration of the initial exogenous shock, and thus precipitates the crisis, is the leverage of the participants, which forces them to liquidate. This in turn drops prices further, forcing more liquidation. And, as I point out in this post and in other places (including my book), the next step is selling in other markets, leading to contagion.

Wednesday, February 11, 2009

Merging two zombie banks is like have two drunks trying to help each other to stand up.

From Paul Kedrosky:

"
QOTD: Roubini on Zombie Banks, and Plan "N"

Merging two zombie banks is like have two drunks trying to help each other to stand up.
-- Nouriel Roubini (RGE Monitor -- 02/10/09)

The entire Roubini piece on bank nationalization -- or Plan "N" as he calls it -- is worth a close read, with these being the key paragraphs:

So why is the US government temporizing and avoiding doing the right thing, i.e. take over the insolvent banks? There are two reasons. First, there is still some small hope and a small probability that the economy will recover sooner than expected, that expected credit losses will be smaller than expected and that the current approach of recapping the banks and somehow working out the bad assets will work in due time. Second, taking over the banks – call is nationalization or, in a more politically correct way, “receivership” – is a radical action that requires most banks be clearly beyond pale and insolvent to be undertaken. Today Citi and Bank of America clearly look like near-insolvent and ready to be taken over but JPMorgan and Wells Fargo do not yet. But with the sharp rise in delinquencies and charge-off rates that we are experiencing now on mortgages, commercial real estate and consumer credit in a matter of six to twelve months even JPMorgan and Wells will likely look as near-insolvent …

…So while Plan A is now underway today’s very negative market response to this Treasury plan suggest that it will not fly. Markets were expecting a more clear plan but also a plan that would bail out shareholders and creditors of insolvent banks. Unfortunately that is not politically and fiscally feasible. It is thus time to start to think and plan ahead for for Plan N (“nationalization” of insolvent banks).

Nouriel pretty much nails it."

Me:

The banks are more like vampires than zombies. Roubini and Taleb are correct about Nationalization. The argument that the government can't run anything, even for a short time, after bankers have led us to financial ruin is strange. Also, the FDIC is the government. It will, in fact, take over the banks, since allowing banks to fail without the FDIC swooping in might lead to a bank run, which is the last thing we need. The way the market would signal a failing bank is a bank run, which is why the FDIC swoops in unannounced as a rule, if I'm not mistaken.

Tuesday, February 10, 2009

Here is how economists and others reacted to Mr. Geithner’s speech

From the NY Times:

"
Reactions to Geithner’s Speech

Updated 3:33 p.m. with more reaction

In a press conference in Washington on Tuesday, the Treasury secretary, Timothy F. Geithner, announced the government’s new plan of action to rescue the banking system.

Here is how economists and others reacted to Mr. Geithner’s speech:

Brian Bethune, IHS Global Insight: “The bottom line from the Geithner speech is that it was too general, and it lacked the specifics needed to it to be credible - the speech and its preamble had too many political overtones that did not set the stage appropriately for essentially a key communication that was directed to mainly a technical audience from a key administration technocrat.”

Nassim Taleb, New York University Polytechnic Institute: “This plan is coming from those who missed the crisis and still don’t understand what’s going on. It does not address the fundamental problem we are facing: the economic system is fragile and needs what I call “robustification to Black Swans” through deleveraging, a transition into what I call Capitalism 2.0. I don’t understand 1) why we need to force people to borrow more when, if anything, we need to de-leverage by turning debt into equity or restructuring existing debt — it is like giving more cocaine to an addict experiencing withdrawal symptoms and calling it a “solution”; 2) it does not do what to me is the essential need of the system: nationalize the banks and snatch control from the bankers because they have vicious incentives to take risks at society’s expense — and proved it with the first plan. In short: it has already failed.”

Daniel Alpert, Westwood Capital, LLC: “There is much to be admired in the Financial Stability Plan unveiled by Treasury Secretary Tim Geithner in his presentation this morning. We particularly applaud the emphasis on the stress testing of large banks to determine their ability to survive in a deteriorating economic environment. Nevertheless, we are a bit incredulous as to why the Secretary (and, it is apparent from insider reports, that his views prevailed on this score) placed such heavy emphasis on protecting the economic stakes of existing holders of the common shares of troubled banks when the government will still be required to inject billions more to restore capitalization to large systemically critical institutions.”

Douglas Elliott, The Brookings Institution: “The bad bank, which will be fleshed out over the next several weeks, will be extremely tricky to design effectively. At best, it will be modestly inferior to the solution of providing a guaranteed floor value for toxic assets without requiring banks to sell them to gain the protection. At worst, the plan may fizzle by failing to achieve a large volume of purchases or may prove considerably more expensive for taxpayers than anticipated. On the positive side, continuing to offer substantial capital injections to banks, despite the intense political unpopularity of those done under the Bush Administration, shows a measure of political courage.”

Jan Hatzius, Goldman Sachs U.S. Economic Research: “As expected, the Treasury’s financial rescue plan will work within the constraints of existing TARP funding (of which about $350bn remains), attempting to catalyze private sector funds to purchase bad assets and restart the securitization process. However, the speech and accompanying fact sheet leave open many questions about the timing of these interventions and the terms of asset purchases and recapitalization. Much of the program clearly remains to be worked out over the coming weeks and months.”

Robert Reich, University of California, Berkeley: “The Treasury doesn’t have the entire plan worked out yet, and also needs some wiggle room in case certain aspects prove unworkable. Too much detail can also attract the attention of critics who will inevitably find fault or raise awkward questions. Remember: Nothing has ever been tried on this scale before. But…[t]he public wants specificity in terms of where the second tranche of TARP’s $350 billion is going, and exactly how it will translate into more loans and more help for distressed homeowners — and will surely demand more specificity if Geithner comes back for additional authorization. More to the point, investors (whoever they are) need lots of specificity before they’re going to put up a single dollar, no matter how much of their downside risk is assumed by the government.”

Mark Gertler, New York University: “It’s first important to recognize that Geithner had to choose from a set of highly imperfect options: There is no magic bullet. With this in mind I think the general thrust of program is in the right direction. From the experience of the last few months we have learned that the way out of this crisis is ultimately going to require cleaning toxic assets off bank balance sheets. The main obstacle to doing so is finding a way to price the assets. The proposed the joint public/private venture is probably the best way to attack this problem. We don’t yet have the full details of how this will work, but I expect we will hear in the next weeks.”

Peter Schiff, Euro Pacific Capital: “Perhaps the centerpiece of today’s announcement is the commitment up to $1 trillion to revivify the collapsed market for securitized debt that previously allowed unprecedented levels of lending in the home, auto, student, and credit card sectors. Geithner makes the false assumption securitization is a prerequisite for healthy markets. Our nation’s short history with widely securitized debt has simply shown that the process can lead to massive mispricing of assets and risk. But, in the worldview of Geithner and his fellow economists, credit, rather than savings, is [the] central figure in the economic equation. In his mind, anything that eases the process of lending is an end in itself. In so doing this plan guarantees that the U.S. economy will be pushed farther and farther out on a leveraged limb, until no amount of market medicine can prevent a total economic collapse.”




Me:

“2) it does not do what to me is the essential need of the system: nationalize the banks and snatch control from the bankers because they have vicious incentives to take risks at society’s expense — and proved it with the first plan. In short: it has already failed.”

At least one person gets it. We need to exert real moral hazard by seizing these banks. It’s what the banks fear, as is shown by the lengths that are being taken to avoid it. Without that, this plan goes nowhere except to the taxpayers wallets, where it will deposit huge losses from the banks. What a pity.

— Don the libertarian Democrat

Monday, February 9, 2009

Taleb, like me, wants to get rid of risk-taking by banks

From Arnold Kling:

"Over at econtalk, Russ Roberts interviews Daron Acemoglu. Self-recommending, as Tyler would say.

Also, here is a video featuring Daniel Kahneman and Nassim Taleb. Taleb, like me, wants to get rid of risk-taking by banks, and leave non-insured institutions free to take whatever risks they want, as long as they are not creating risks for others. His solution is to nationalize banks. (me: why would this mean that they would not take risks? Suppose that Freddie Mac and Fannie Mae had been fully nationalized as of three years ago. Would they have taken more risk or less risk?)

Kahneman tells a story of Swiss army men who got lost in blizzard in the Alps. When they finally find their way back, they are asked, "How did you find your way?" They say, "We had a map." But the map is of the Pyrenees! Kahneman's point is that people have a lot more confidence if they have maps, even if those maps are wrong.

Taleb does not explicitly dispute this point, but he clearly does not like the notion. It would imply that you want a doctor to think he is correct, even if he is wrong, because the doctor is giving you a map. Taleb says that religion succeeded because when people had faith, they stayed away from doctors, who were wrong. (He makes those sorts of comments a lot, as you know.) He wants business schools to stop giving students the "map" of financial modeling, because he thinks those models are wrong.

In my Lost History of Macroeconometrics, I say that macroeconometrics tries to satisfy the need for a map, but it does not provide a reliable map. But I am in the same position as Taleb. People want to believe in a map, so telling them they have the wrong map is not going to get me very far.

Finally, a reminder that on Tuesday, February 10, I will be speaking here. If they don't record it, I'll try to remember what I said. (I try not to use notes or a text. Instead, I prepare by practicing while I walk. These days, if you're talking to yourself while walking, people just assume you are on the phone, so they don't even look at you funny.)"

Me:

"Taleb, like me, wants to get rid of risk-taking by banks, and leave non-insured institutions free to take whatever risks they want, as long as they are not creating risks for others. His solution is to nationalize banks. (me: why would this mean that they would not take risks? Suppose that Freddie Mac and Fannie Mae had been fully nationalized as of three years ago. Would they have taken more risk or less risk?)"

Although I'd like to nationalize a few banks in this mess, I agree with you. We don't need to run them, especially if we have narrow/limited purpose banks. I didn't like this idea at first, but if it allows the existence of risk-taking non-insured institutions, then I'd be for it.

Monday, January 5, 2009

"Much of today’s financial regulation assumes that risk can be accurately measured"

A view about regulation on Vox from Jon Danielsson:

"
The myth of the riskometer

Much of today’s financial regulation assumes( MECHANISTIC EXPLANATION ) that risk can be accurately measured – that financial engineers, like civil engineers, can design safe products with sophisticated maths informed by historical estimates. But, as the crisis has shown, the laws of finance react to financial engineers’ creations, rendering risk calculations invalid. Regulators should rely on simpler methods.(HUMAN AGENCY EXPLANATIONS )

There is a widely held belief that financial risk is easily measured – that we can stick some sort of riskometer( CAN'T BE DONE ) deep into the bowels of the financial system and get an accurate measurement of the risk of complex financial instruments. Such misguided belief in this riskometer played a key role in getting the financial system into the mess it is in.

Unfortunately, the lessons have not been learned. Risk sensitivity is expected to play a key role both in the future regulatory system and new areas such as executive compensation.

Origins of the myth

Where does this belief come from? Perhaps the riskometer is incredibly clever – after all, it is designed by some of the smartest people around, using incredibly sophisticated mathematics.

Perhaps this belief also comes from what we know about physics. By understanding the laws of nature, engineers are able to create the most amazing things. If we can leverage the laws of nature into an Airbus 380, we surely must be able to leverage the laws of finance into a CDO.

This is false. The laws of finance are not the same as the laws of nature. The engineer, by understanding physics, can create structures that are safe regardless of what natures throws at them because the engineer reacts to nature but nature does not generally react to the engineer.( NOT IN THE SAME WAY )

The problem is endogenous risk

In physics, complexity is a virtue( NO. SIMPLICITY IS A VIRTUE. ). It enables us to create supercomputers and iPods. In finance, complexity used to be a virtue. The more complex the instruments are, the more opaque they are, and the more money you make. So long as the underlying risk assumptions are correct( USEFUL ), the complex product is sound. In finance, complexity has become a vice( JUSTIFICATION FOR UNSOUND INVESTMENTS ).

We can create the most sophisticated financial models, but immediately when they are put to use, the financial system changes. Outcomes in the financial system aggregate intelligent human behaviour( TRUE. BUT THAT'S TRUE OF ALL OF THE HUMAN SCIENCES. ). Therefore attempting to forecast prices or risk using past observations is generally impossible( THAT'S FALSE. PREDICTING THE FUTURE PERFECTLY ISN'T POSSIBLE. ). This is what Hyun Song Shin and I called endogenous risk (Danielsson and Shin 2003).( IT'S NOT THAT PROFOUND )

Because of endogenous risk, financial risk forecasting is one of the hardest things we do( SO WHAT? ). In Danielsson (2008), I tried what is perhaps the easiest risk modelling exercise there is – forecasting value-at-risk for IBM stock. The resulting number was about +/- 30% accurate, depending on the model and assumptions. And this is the best case scenario. Trying to model the risk in more complicated assets is much more inaccurate. +/- 30% accurate is the best we can do( THE BEST YOU CAN DO ).

Applying the riskometer

The inaccuracy of risk modelling does not prevent us from trying to measure risk, and when we have such a measurement, we can create the most amazing structures – CDOs, SIVs, CDSs, and the entire alphabet soup of instruments limited only by our mathematical ability and imagination. Unfortunately, if the underlying foundation is based on sand, the whole structure becomes unstable. What the quants missed was that the underlying assumptions were false.( ABOUT MODELS AND REALITY, YES. )

We don’t seem to be learning the lesson, as argued by Taleb and Triana (2008), that “risk methods that failed dramatically in the real world continue to be taught to students”, adding “a method heavily grounded( HERE'S THE PROBLEM ) on those same quantitative and theoretical principles, called Value at Risk, continued to be widely used. It was this that was to blame for the crisis( I DON'T AGREE ).”

When complicated models are used to create financial products, the designer looks at historical prices for guidance. If in history prices are generally increasing and risk is apparently low, that will become the prediction for the future( IF YOU'RE A ROBOT ). Thus a bubble is created( THAT'S NOT THE CAUSE OF A BUBBLE. SORRY. ). Increasing prices feed into the models, inflating valuations, inflating prices more. This is how most models work( BUT NOT PEOPLE ), and this is why models are often so wrong. We cannot stick a riskometer( THERE ISN'T ONE ) into a CDO and get an accurate reading.

Risk sensitivity and financial regulations

One of the biggest problems leading up to the crisis was the twin belief that risk could be modelled( IT'S JUST A MODEL ) and that complexity was good( NOT GOOD ). Certainly the regulators who made risk sensitivity the centrepiece of the Basel 2 Accord believed this.

Under Basel 2, bank capital is risk-sensitive. What that means is that a financial institution is required to measure the riskiness of its assets, and the riskier the assets the more capital it has to hold. At a first glance, this is a sensible idea, after all why should we not want capital to reflect riskiness? But there are at least three main problems:( 1 ) the measurement of risk, ( 2 )procyclicality (see Danielsson et. al 2001), and the( 3 ) determination of capital.

To have risk-sensitive capital we need to measure risk, i.e. apply the riskometer. In the absence of accurate( TRUE ) risk measurements, risk-sensitive bank capital is at best meaningless and at worst dangerous.

Risk-sensitive capital can( MAYBE ) be dangerous because it gives a false sense of security. In the same way it is so hard to measure risk, it is also easy to manipulate risk measurements( THIS IS TRUE ). It is a straightforward exercise to manipulate risk measurements to give vastly different outcomes in an entirely plausible and justifiable manner, without affecting the real underlying risk. A financial institution can easily report low risk levels whilst deliberately or otherwise assuming much higher risk. This of course means that risk calculations used for the calculation of capital are inevitably suspect.( HERE I AGREE )

The financial engineering premium

Related to this is the problem of determining what exactly is capital. The standards for determining capital are not set in stone; they vary between countries and even between institutions. Indeed, a vast industry of capital structure experts exists explicitly to manipulate capital, making capital appear as high as possible while making it in reality as low as possible( TRUE. LEVERAGING. ).

The unreliability of capital calculations becomes especially visible when we compare standard capital calculations under international standards with the American leverage ratio. The leverage ratio limits the capital to assets ratio of banks and is therefore a much more conservative measure of capital than the risk-based capital of Basel 2. Because it is more conservative, it is much harder to manipulate.( IT'S ALSO MORE CONSERVATIVE, AND INHERENTLY LESS RISKY. I DON'T FOLLOW THE HARDER ARGUMENT. )

One thing we have learned in the crisis is that banks that were thought to have adequate capital have been found lacking( AND? ). A number of recent studies have looked at the various calculations of bank capital and found that some of the most highly capitalised banks under Basel 2 are the lowest capitalised under the leverage ratio, an effect we could call the financial engineering premium.( NO. COMPLETELY WRONG. THE BANKS AND INVESTORS WERE LOOKING FOR WAYS TO CUT CAPITAL RESTRICTIONS. THAT'S WHY THEY CHOSE CDSs, CDOs, AND THE MATH MODELS THAT JUSTIFY THEM. THEY COULD HAVE CHOSEN OTHER LESS MATHEMATICAL WAYS OF DOING THIS. )

As Philipp Hildebrand (2008) of the Swiss National Bank recently observed “Looking at risk-based capital measures, the two large Swiss banks were among the best-capitalised large international banks in the world. Looking at simple leverage( THAT'S ALWAYS WHAT YOU NEED TO LOOK AT ), however, these institutions were among the worst-capitalised banks”

The riskometer and bonuses

We are now seeing risk sensitivity applied to new areas such as executive compensation. A recent example is a report from UBS (2008) on their future model for compensation, where it is stated that “variable compensation will be based on clear performance criteria which are linked to risk-adjusted value creation.” The idea seems laudable – of course we want the compensation of UBS executives to be increasingly risk sensitive.

The problem is that whilst such risk sensitivity may be intuitively and theoretically attractive, it is difficult or impossible to achieve in practice. One thing we have learned in the crisis is that executives have been able to assume much more risk than desired by the bank( TRUE ). A key reason why they were able to do so was that they understood the models and the risk in their own positions much better than other parts of the bank( TRUE ). It is hard to see why more risk-sensitive compensation would solve that problem. After all, the individual who has the deepest understanding of positions and the models is in the best place to manipulate the risk models. Increasing the risk sensitivity of executive compensation seems to be the lazy way out.( THERE ARE BETTER WAYS )

This problem might not be too bad because UBS will not pay out all the bonuses in one go, instead, “Even if an executive leaves the company, the balance (i.e. remaining bonuses) will be kept at-risk for a period of three years in order to capture any tail risk events.” Unfortunately, the fact that a tail event is realised does not by itself imply that tail risk was high, and conversely, the absence of such an event does not imply risk was low. If UBS denies bonus payments when losses occur in the future and pays them out when no losses occur, all it has accomplished is rewarding the lucky and inviting lawsuits from the unlucky. The underlying problem is not really solved.( NOT REALLY, NO )

Conclusion

The myth of the riskometer is alive and kicking. In spite of a large body of empirical evidence identifying the difficulties in measuring financial risk, policymakers and financial institutions alike continue to promote risk sensitivity.

The reasons may have to do with the fact that risk sensitivity is intuitively attractive, and the counter arguments complex. The crisis, however, shows us the folly of the riskometer. Let us hope that decision makers will rely on other methods.

References

Danielsson, Jon and Hyun Song Shin, 2003, “Endogenous Risk”, chapter in Modern Risk Management: A History.
Danielsson, Jon, Paul Embrechts, Charles Goodhart, Con Keating, Felix Muennich, Olivier Renault and Hyun Song Shin (2001) “An Academic Response to Basel II”, 2001.
Danielsson, Jon (2008) “Blame the models”, VoxEU.org, 8 May 2008
Hildebrand, Philipp M. (2008) “Is Basel II Enough? The Benefits of a Leverage Ratio”, Financial Markets Group Lecture, London School of Economics .
Taleb, Nassim Nicholas and Pablo Triana (2008) “Bystanders to this financial crime were manyFinancial Times December 7.
UBS (2008) “Compensation report: UBS’s new compensation model

This is a strange argument. There is no riskometer. There are math models that are more or less useful. I don't see any argument that they can't be useful. Blaming the crisis on math models is itself a mechanistic explanation, based upon an incorrect understanding of how and why theories are useful. A theory or model can have very limited scope and be useful.

A warning about how models relate to the world is important, but it is possible to measure( although I don't like the word "measure" ) risk. If it weren't, no one would do anything.

Saturday, January 3, 2009

"When Wall Street stopped looking for dragons, nothing was going to save it. Not even VaR."

From Joe Nocera on the NY Times:

Zohar Lazar

Zohar Lazar

Christoph Niemann

Brian Cronin

Adrian Tomine

Gary Taxali

Christoph Niemann

Ronald Kurniawan

‘The story that I have to tell is marked all the way through by a persistent tension between those who assert that the best decisions are based on( 1 ) quantification and numbers, determined by the patterns of the past, and those who base their decisions on( 2 ) more subjective degrees of belief about the uncertain future. This is a controversy that has never been resolved( TRUE ).’

— FROM THE INTRODUCTION TO ‘‘AGAINST THE GODS: THE REMARKABLE STORY OF RISK,’’ BY PETER L. BERNSTEIN

THERE AREN’T MANY widely told anecdotes about the current financial crisis, at least not yet, but there’s one that made the rounds in 2007, back when the big investment banks were first starting to write down billions of dollars in mortgage-backed derivatives and other so-called toxic securities. This was well before Bear Stearns collapsed, before Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac were taken over by the federal government, before Lehman fell and Merrill Lynch was sold and A.I.G. saved, before the $700 billion bailout bill was rushed into law. Before, that is, it became obvious that the risks taken by the largest banks and investment firms in the United States — and, indeed, in much of the Western world — were so excessive and foolhardy that they threatened to bring down the financial system itself. On the contrary: this was back when the major investment firms were still assuring investors that all was well, these little speed bumps notwithstanding — assurances based, in part, on their fantastically complex mathematical models( THIS IS WHERE THE REAL COMPLEXITY IS ) for measuring the risk in their various portfolios.

There are many such models, but by far the most widely used is called VaR — Value at Risk. Built around statistical ideas and probability theories that have been around for centuries, VaR was developed and popularized in the early 1990s by a handful of scientists and mathematicians — “quants,” they’re called in the business — who went to work for JPMorgan. VaR’s great appeal, and its great selling point to people who do not happen to be quants, is that it expresses risk as a single number, a dollar figure, no less.

VaR isn’t one model but rather a group of related models that share a mathematical framework. In its most common form, it measures the boundaries of risk in a portfolio over short durations, assuming a “normal” market. For instance, if you have $50 million of weekly VaR, that means that over the course of the next week, there is a 99 percent chance that your portfolio won’t lose more than $50 million. That portfolio could consist of equities, bonds, derivatives or all of the above; one reason VaR became so popular is that it is the only commonly used risk measure that can be applied to just about any asset class. And it takes into account a head-spinning variety of variables, including diversification, leverage and volatility, that make up the kind of market risk that traders and firms face every day.

Another reason VaR is so appealing is that it can measure both individual risks — the amount of risk contained in a single trader’s portfolio, for instance — and firmwide risk, which it does by combining the VaRs of a given firm’s trading desks and coming up with a net number. Top executives usually know their firm’s daily VaR within minutes of the market’s close.

Risk managers use VaR to quantify their firm’s risk positions to their board. In the late 1990s, as the use of derivatives was exploding, the Securities and Exchange Commission ruled that firms had to include a quantitative disclosure of market risks in their financial statements for the convenience of investors, and VaR became the main tool for doing so. Around the same time, an important international rule-making body, the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, went even further to validate VaR by saying that firms and banks could rely on their own internal VaR calculations to set their capital requirements. So long as their VaR was reasonably low, the amount of money they had to set aside to cover risks that might go bad could also be low.

Given the calamity that has since occurred, there has been a great deal of talk, even in quant circles, that this widespread institutional reliance on VaR was a terrible mistake. At the very least, the risks that VaR measured did not include the biggest risk of all: the possibility of a financial meltdown. “Risk modeling didn’t help as much as it should have,” says Aaron Brown, a former risk manager at Morgan Stanley who now works at AQR, a big quant-oriented hedge fund. A risk consultant named Marc Groz says, “VaR is a very limited tool.” David Einhorn, who founded Greenlight Capital, a prominent hedge fund, wrote not long ago that VaR was “relatively useless as a risk-management tool and potentially catastrophic when its use creates a false sense of security among senior managers and watchdogs. This is like an air bag that works all the time, except when you have a car accident.” Nassim Nicholas Taleb, the best-selling author of “The Black Swan,” has crusaded against VaR for more than a decade. He calls it, flatly, “a fraud.”

How then do we account for that story that made the rounds in the summer of 2007? It concerns Goldman Sachs, the one Wall Street firm that was not, at that time, taking a hit for billions of dollars of suddenly devalued mortgage-backed securities. Reporters wanted to understand how Goldman had somehow sidestepped the disaster that had befallen everyone else. What they discovered was that in December 2006, Goldman’s various indicators, including VaR and other risk models, began suggesting that something was wrong. Not hugely wrong, mind you, but wrong enough to warrant a closer look.

“We look at the P.& L. of our businesses every day,” said Goldman Sachs’ chief financial officer, David Viniar, when I went to see him recently to hear the story for myself. (P.& L. stands for profit and loss.) “We have lots of models here that are important, but none are more important than the P.& L., and we check every day to make sure our P.& L. is consistent with where our risk models say it should be. In December our mortgage business lost money for 10 days in a row. It wasn’t a lot of money, but by the 10th day we thought that we should sit down and talk about it.”

So Goldman called a meeting of about 15 people, including several risk managers and the senior people on the various trading desks. They examined a thick report that included every trading position the firm held. For the next three hours, they pored over everything. They examined their VaR numbers and their other risk models. They talked about how the mortgage-backed securities market “felt.” “Our guys said that it felt like it was going to get worse before it got better,” Viniar recalled. “So we made a decision: let’s get closer to home.”

In trading parlance, “getting closer to home” means reining in the risk, which in this case meant either getting rid of the mortgage-backed securities or hedging the positions so that if they declined in value, the hedges would counteract the loss with an equivalent gain. Goldman did both. And that’s why, back in the summer of 2007, Goldman Sachs avoided the pain that was being suffered by Bear Stearns, Merrill Lynch, Lehman Brothers and the rest of Wall Street.

The story was told and retold in the business pages. But what did it mean, exactly? The question was always left hanging. Was it an example of the futility of risk modeling or its utility? Did it show that risk models, properly understood, were not a fraud after all but a potentially important signal that trouble was brewing? Or did it suggest instead that a handful of human beings at Goldman Sachs acted wisely by putting their models aside and making “decisions on more subjective degrees of belief about an uncertain future,” as Peter L. Bernstein put it in “Against the Gods?”

To put it in blunter terms, could VaR and the other risk models Wall Street relies on have helped prevent the financial crisis if only Wall Street paid better attention to them? Or did Wall Street’s reliance on them help lead us into the abyss?

One Saturday a few months ago, Taleb, a trim, impeccably dressed, middle-aged man — inexplicably, he won’t give his age — walked into a lobby in the Columbia Business School and headed for a classroom to give a guest lecture. Until that moment, the lobby was filled with students chatting and eating a quick lunch before the afternoon session began, but as soon as they saw Taleb, they streamed toward him, surrounding him and moving with him as he slowly inched his way up the stairs toward an already-crowded classroom. Those who couldn’t get in had to make do with the next classroom over, which had been set up as an overflow room. It was jammed, too.

It’s not every day that an options trader becomes famous by writing a book, but that’s what Taleb did, first with “Fooled by Randomness,” which was published in 2001 and became an immediate cult classic on Wall Street, and more recently with “The Black Swan: The Impact of the Highly Improbable,” which came out in 2007 and landed on a number of best-seller lists. He also went from being primarily an options trader to what he always really wanted to be: a public intellectual. When I made the mistake of asking him one day whether he was an adjunct professor, he quickly corrected me. “I’m the Distinguished Professor of Risk Engineering at N.Y.U.,” he responded. “It’s the highest title they give in that department.” Humility is not among his virtues. On his Web site he has a link that reads, “Quotes from ‘The Black Swan’ that the imbeciles did not want to hear.”

“How many of you took statistics at Columbia?” he asked as he began his lecture. Most of the hands in the room shot up. “You wasted your money,” he sniffed. Behind him was a slide of Mickey Mouse that he had put up on the screen, he said, because it represented “Mickey Mouse probabilities.” That pretty much sums up his view of business-school statistics and probability courses.

Taleb’s ideas can be difficult to follow, in part because he uses the language of academic statisticians; words like “Gaussian,” “kurtosis” and “variance” roll off his tongue. But it’s also because he speaks in a kind of brusque shorthand, acting as if any fool should be able to follow his train of thought, which he can’t be bothered to fully explain.

“This is a Stan O’Neal trade,” he said, referring to the former chief executive of Merrill Lynch. He clicked to a slide that showed a trade that made slow, steady profits — and then quickly spiraled downward for a giant, brutal loss.

“Why do people measure risks against events that took place in 1987?” he asked, referring to Black Monday, the October day when the U.S. market lost more than 20 percent of its value and has been used ever since as the worst-case scenario in many risk models. “Why is that a benchmark? I call it future-blindness.

“If you have a pilot flying a plane who doesn’t understand there can be storms, what is going to happen?” he asked. “He is not going to have a magnificent flight. Any small error is going to crash a plane. This is why the crisis that happened was predictable.”

Eventually, though, you do start to get the point. Taleb says that Wall Street risk models, no matter how mathematically sophisticated, are bogus; indeed, he is the leader of the camp that believes that risk models have done far more harm than good. And the essential reason for this is that the greatest risks are never the ones you can see and measure, but the ones you can’t see and therefore can never measure. The ones that seem so far outside the boundary of normal probability that you can’t imagine they could happen in your lifetime — even though, of course, they do happen, more often than you care to realize. Devastating hurricanes happen. Earthquakes happen. And once in a great while, huge financial catastrophes happen. Catastrophes that risk models somehow always manage to miss.

VaR is Taleb’s favorite case in point. The original VaR measured portfolio risk along what is called a “normal distribution curve,” a statistical measure that was first identified by Carl Friedrich Gauss in the early 1800s (hence the term “Gaussian”). It is a simple bell curve of the sort we are all familiar with.

The reason the normal curve looks the way it does — why it rises as it gets closer to the middle — is that the closer you get to that point, the smaller the change in the thing you’re measuring, and hence the more frequently it is likely to occur. A typical stock or portfolio of stocks, for example, is far likelier to gain or lose one point in a day (or a week) than it is to gain or lose 20 points. So the pattern of normal distribution will cluster around those smaller changes toward the middle of the curve, while the less-frequent distributions will fall along the ends of the curve.

VaR uses this normal distribution curve to plot the riskiness of a portfolio. But it makes certain assumptions. VaR is often measured daily and rarely extends beyond a few weeks, and because it is a very short-term measure, it assumes that tomorrow will be more or less like today. Even what’s called “historical VaR” — a variation of standard VaR that measures potential portfolio risk a year or two out, only uses the previous few years as its benchmark. As the risk consultant Marc Groz puts it, “The years 2005-2006,” which were the culmination of the housing bubble, “aren’t a very good universe for predicting what happened in 2007-2008.”

This was one of Alan Greenspan’s primary excuses when he made his mea culpa for the financial crisis before Congress a few months ago. After pointing out that a Nobel Prize had been awarded for work that led to some of the theories behind derivative pricing and risk management, he said: “The whole intellectual edifice, however, collapsed in the summer of last year because the data input into the risk-management models generally covered only the past two decades, a period of euphoria. Had instead the models been fitted more appropriately to historic periods of stress, capital requirements would have been much higher and the financial world would be in far better shape today, in my judgment.” Well, yes. That was also the point Taleb was making in his lecture when he referred to what he called future-blindness. People tend not to be able to anticipate a future they have never personally experienced.

Yet even faulty historical data isn’t Taleb’s primary concern. What he cares about, with standard VaR, is not the number that falls within the 99 percent probability. He cares about what happens in the other 1 percent, at the extreme edge of the curve. The fact that you are not likely to lose more than a certain amount 99 percent of the time tells you absolutely nothing about what could happen the other 1 percent of the time. You could lose $51 million instead of $50 million — no big deal. That happens two or three times a year, and no one blinks an eye. You could also lose billions and go out of business. VaR has no way of measuring which it will be.

What will cause you to lose billions instead of millions? Something rare, something you’ve never considered a possibility. Taleb calls these events “fat tails” or “black swans,” and he is convinced that they take place far more frequently than most human beings are willing to contemplate. Groz has his own way of illustrating the problem: he showed me a slide he made of a curve with the letters “T.B.D.” at the extreme ends of the curve. I thought the letters stood for “To Be Determined,” but that wasn’t what Groz meant. “T.B.D. stands for ‘There Be Dragons,’ ” he told me.

And that’s the point. Because we don’t know what a black swan might look like or when it might appear and therefore don’t plan for it, it will always get us in the end. “Any system susceptible to a black swan will eventually blow up,” Taleb says. The modern system of world finance, complex and interrelated and opaque, where what happened yesterday can and does affect what happens tomorrow, and where one wrong tug of the thread can cause it all to unravel, is just such a system.

“I have been calling for the abandonment of certain risk measures since 1996 because they cause people to cross the street blindfolded,” he said toward the end of his lecture. “The system went bust because nobody listened to me.”

After the lecture, the professor who invited Taleb to Columbia took a handful of people out for a late lunch at a nearby diner. Somewhat surprisingly, given Taleb’s well-known scorn for risk managers, the professor had also invited several risk managers who worked at two big investment banks. We had barely been seated before they tried to engage Taleb in a debate over the value of VaR. But Taleb is impossible to argue with on this subject; every time they raised an objection to his argument, he curtly dismissed them out of hand. “VaR can be useful,” said one of the risk managers. “It depends on how you use it. It can be useful in identifying trends.”

“This argument is addressed in ‘The Black Swan,’ ” Taleb retorted. “Not a single person has offered me an argument I haven’t heard.”

“I think VaR is great,” said another risk manager. “I think it is a fantastic tool. It’s like an altimeter in aircraft. It has some margin for error, but if you’re a pilot, you know how to deal with it. But very few pilots give up using it.”

Taleb replied: “Altimeters have errors that are Gaussian. You can compensate. In the real world, the magnitude of errors is much less known.”

Around and around they went, talking past each other for the next hour or so. It was engaging but unsatisfying; it didn’t help illuminate the role risk management played in the crisis.

The conversation had an energizing effect on Taleb, however. He walked out of the diner with a full head of steam, railing about the two “imbeciles” he just had to endure. I used the moment to ask if he knew the people at RiskMetrics, a successful risk-management consulting firm that spun out of the original JPMorgan quant effort in the mid-1990s. “They’re intellectual charlatans,” he replied dismissively. “You can quote me on that.”

As we approached his car, he began talking about his own performance in 2008. Although he is no longer a full-time trader, he remains a principal in a hedge fund he helped found, Black Swan Protection Protocol. His fund makes trades that either gain or lose small amounts of money in normal times but can make oversize gains when a black swan appears. Taleb likes to say that, as a trader, he has made money only three times in his life — in the crash of 1987, during the dot-com bust more than a decade later and now. But all three times he has made a killing. With the world crashing around it, his fund was up 65 to 115 percent for the year. Taleb chuckled. “They wouldn’t listen to me,” he said finally. “So I decided, to hell with them, I’ll take their money instead.”

“VaR WAS INEVITABLE,” Gregg Berman of RiskMetrics said when I went to see him a few days later. He didn’t sound like an intellectual charlatan. His explanation of the utility of VaR — and its limitations — made a certain undeniable sense. He did, however, sound like somebody who was completely taken aback by the amount of blame placed on risk modeling since the financial crisis began.

“Obviously, we are big proponents of risk models,” he said. “But a computer does not do risk modeling. People do it( FINALLY, THE MAIN POINT ). And people got overzealous and they stopped being careful. They took on too much leverage( VERY TRUE. BUT THAT WAS THE POINT OF CDSs AND CDOs IN THE FIRST PLACE. IN OTHER WORDS, LEVERAGE WASN'T A BYPRODUCT, IT WAS THE GOAL. ). And whether they had models that missed that, or they weren’t paying enough attention, I don’t know. But I do think that this was much more a failure of management than of risk management. I think blaming models for this would be very unfortunate because you are placing blame on a mathematical equation. You can’t blame math( I AGREE COMPLETELY. HOWEVER, MY VERSION OF TALEB IS THAT HE IS SAYING THE SAME THING. ),” he added with some exasperation.

Although Berman, who is 42, was a founding partner of RiskMetrics, it turned out that he was one of the few at the firm who hadn’t come from JPMorgan. Still, he knew the back story. How could he not? It was part of the lore of the place. Indeed, it was part of the lore of VaR.

The late 1980s and the early 1990s were a time when many firms were trying to devise more sophisticated risk models because the world was changing around them. Banks, whose primary risk had long been credit risk — the risk that a loan might not be paid back( THAT IS IN FACT THE WHAT THE PROBLEM WITH SUBPRIME AND OTHER MORTGAGES IS. THESE BAD LOANS CANNOT BE BLAMED ON MATH MODELS. IT IS STRAIGHTFORWARD CREDIT RISK. ) — were starting to meld with investment banks, which traded stocks and bonds. Derivatives and securitizations — those pools of mortgages or credit-card loans that were bundled by investment firms and sold to investors — were becoming an increasingly important component of Wall Street. But they were devilishly complicated to value( THEN THEY ARE INHERENTLY RISKY. WHY DO YOU THINK PEOPLE WANT US TREASURIES NOW? ONE REASON IS THAT THE ARE LIQUID=LESS RISKY ). For one thing, many of the more arcane instruments didn’t trade very often, so you had to try to value them by finding a comparable security that did trade( RISKY ). And they were sliced into different pieces — tranches they’re called — each of which had a different risk component( REALLY NO DIFFERENT THAN DIFFERENT GRADES OF BONDS. ). In addition every desk had its own way of measuring risk that was largely incompatible with every other desk.

JPMorgan’s chairman at the time VaR took off was a man named Dennis Weatherstone. Weatherstone, who died in 2008 at the age of 77, was a working-class Englishman who acquired the bearing of a patrician during his long career at the bank. He was soft-spoken, polite, self-effacing. At the point at which he took over JPMorgan, it had moved from being purely a commercial bank into one of these new hybrids. Within the bank, Weatherstone had long been known as an expert on risk, especially when he was running the foreign-exchange trading desk. But as chairman, he quickly realized that he understood far less about the firm’s overall risk than he needed to. Did the risk in JPMorgan’s stock portfolio cancel out the risk being taken by its bond portfolio — or did it heighten those risks? How could you compare different kinds of derivative risks? What happened to the portfolio when volatility increased or interest rates rose? How did currency fluctuations affect the fixed-income instruments? Weatherstone had no idea what the answers were. He needed a way to compare the risks of those various assets and to understand what his companywide risk was.( I'M NOT SURE THAT I UNDERSTAND THIS. IF NOTHING IS RISKY, HOW DOES IT ADD UP TO RISKY? )

The answer the bank’s quants had come up with was Value at Risk. To phrase it that way is to make it sound as if a handful of math whizzes locked themselves in a room one day, cranked out some formulas, and — presto! — they had a risk-management system. In fact, it took around seven years, according to Till Guldimann, an elegant, Swiss-born, former JPMorgan banker who ran the team that devised VaR and who is now vice chairman of SunGard Data Systems. “VaR is not just one invention,” he said. “You solved one problem and another cropped up. At first it seemed unmanageable. But as we refined it, the methodologies got better.”

Early on, the group decided that it wanted to come up with a number it could use to gauge the possibility that any kind of portfolio could lose a certain amount of money over the next 24 hours, within a 95 percent probability. (Many firms still use the 95 percent VaR, though others prefer 99 percent.) That became the core concept. When the portfolio changed, as traders bought and sold securities the next day, the VaR was then recalculated, allowing everyone to see whether the new trades had added to, or lessened, the firm’s risk( THIS MAKES SENSE ).

“There was a lot of suspicion internally,” recalls Guldimann, because traders and executives — nonquants — didn’t believe that such a thing could be quantified mathematically. But they were wrong. Over time, as VaR was proved more correct than not day after day, quarter after quarter, the top executives came not only to believe in it but also to rely on it( VERY BAD ).

For instance, during his early years as a risk manager, pre-VaR, Guldimann often confronted the problem of what to do when a trader had reached his trading limit but believed he should be given more capital to play out his hand. “How would I know if he should get the increase?” Guldimann says. “All I could do is ask around. Is he a good guy? Does he know what he’s doing? It was ridiculous. Once we converted all the limits to VaR limits, we could compare. You could look at the profits the guy made and compare it to his VaR. If the guy who asked for a higher limit was making more money with lower VaR” — that is, with less risk — “it was a good basis to give him the money.”( THIS DOES MAKE SENSE )

By the early 1990s, VaR had become such a fixture at JPMorgan that Weatherstone instituted what became known as the 415 report because it was handed out every day at 4:15, just after the market closed. It allowed him to see what every desk’s estimated profit and loss was, as compared to its risk, and how it all added up for the entire firm. True, it didn’t take into account Taleb’s fat tails, but nobody really expected it to do that( YES ). Weatherstone had been a trader himself; he understood both the limits and the value of VaR. It told him things he hadn’t known before. He could use it to help him make judgments( YES ) about whether the firm should take on additional risk or pull back. And that’s what he did.

What caused VaR to catapult above the risk systems being developed by JPMorgan competitors was what the firm did next: it gave VaR away. In 1993, Guldimann made risk the theme of the firm’s annual client conference. Many of the clients were so impressed with the JPMorgan approach that they asked if they could purchase the underlying system. JPMorgan decided it didn’t want to get into that business, but proceeded instead to form a small group, RiskMetrics, that would teach the concept to anyone who wanted to learn it, while also posting it on the Internet so that other risk experts could make suggestions to improve it. As Guldimann wrote years later, “Many wondered what the bank was trying to accomplish by giving away ‘proprietary’ methodologies and lots of data, but not selling any products or services.” He continued, “It popularized a methodology and made it a market standard, and it enhanced the image of JPMorgan.”

JPMorgan later spun RiskMetrics off into its own consulting company. By then, VaR had become so popular that it was considered the risk-model gold standard. Here was the odd thing, though: the month RiskMetrics went out on its own, September 1998, was also when Long-Term Capital Management “blew up.” L.T.C.M. was a fantastically successful hedge fund famous for its quantitative trading approach and its belief, supposedly borne out by its risk models, that it was taking minimal risk.( THIS IS A VERY IMPORTANT POINT )

L.T.C.M.’s collapse would seem to make a pretty good case for Taleb’s theories. What brought the firm down was a black swan it never saw coming: the twin financial crises in Asia and Russia. Indeed, so sure were the firm’s partners that the market would revert to “normal”( THIS IS SILLY. ) — which is what their model insisted would happen — that they continued to take on exposures that would destroy the firm as the crisis worsened, according to Roger Lowenstein’s account of the debacle, “When Genius Failed.” Oh, and another thing: among the risk models the firm relied on was VaR.

Aaron Brown, the former risk manager at Morgan Stanley, remembers thinking that the fall of L.T.C.M. could well lead to the demise of VaR. “It thoroughly punctured the myth that VaR was invincible( TRUE ),” he said. “Something that fails to live up to perfection is more despised than something that was never idealized in the first place.” After the 1987 market crash, for example, portfolio insurance, which had been sold by Wall Street as a risk-mitigation device, became largely discredited.

But that didn’t happen with VaR. There was so much schadenfreude associated with L.T.C.M. — it had Nobel Prize winners among its partners! — that it was easy for the rest of Wall Street to view its fall as an example of comeuppance. And for a hedge fund that promoted the ingeniousness of its risk measures, it took far greater risks than it ever acknowledged.

For these reasons, other firms took to rationalizing away the fall of L.T.C.M.; they viewed it as a human failure( IT WAS ) rather than a failure of risk modeling. The collapse only amplified the feeling on Wall Street that firms needed to be able to understand their risks for the entire firm. Only VaR could do that. And finally, there was a belief among some, especially after the crisis abated, that the events that brought down L.T.C.M. were one in a million. We would never see anything like that again in our lifetime( SILLY ).

So instead of diminishing in importance, VaR become a more important part of the financial scene. The Securities and Exchange Commission, for instance, worried about the amount of risk that derivatives posed to the system, mandated that financial firms would have to disclose that risk to investors( GOOD ), and VaR became the de facto measure( BAD ). If the VaR number increased from year to year in a company’s annual report, it meant the firm was taking more risk. Rather than doing anything to limit the growth of derivatives, the agency concluded( PEOPLE DID ) that disclosure, via VaR, was sufficient.

That, in turn, meant that even firms that had resisted VaR now succumbed. It meant that chief executives of big banks and investment firms had to have at least a passing familiarity with VaR. It meant that traders all had to understand the VaR consequences of making a big bet or of changing their portfolios. Some firms continued to use VaR as a tool while adding other tools as well, like “stress” or “scenario” tests, to see where the weak links in the portfolio were or what might happen if the market dropped drastically. But others viewed VaR as the primary measure they had to concern themselves with.

VaR, in other words, became institutionalized. RiskMetrics went from having a dozen risk-management clients to more than 600. Lots of competitors sprouted up. Long-Term Capital Management became an increasingly distant memory, overshadowed by the Internet boom and then the housing boom. Corporate chieftains like Stanley O’Neal at Merrill Lynch and Charles Prince at Citigroup pushed( YES ) their divisions to take more risk because they were being left behind in the race for trading profits. All over Wall Street, VaR numbers increased, but it still all seemed manageable — and besides, nothing bad was happening!

VaR also became a crutch. When an international banking group that advises national regulators decided the world needed more sophisticated ways to gauge the amount of capital that firms had to hold, Wall Street firms lobbied the group to allow them to use their internal VaR numbers. Ultimately, the group came up with an accord that allowed just that. It doesn’t seem too strong to say that as a direct result( ACTUALLY IT DOES, BECAUSE YOU'RE FOREGETTING THAT LOWER CAPITAL STANDARDS WAS THE WHOLE POINT OF THE EXERCISE. THESE ARE MERELY RATIONALIZATIONS. THEY PROVIDED A VENEER OF SAFETY TO INHERENTLY RISKY INVESTMENTS. ), banks didn’t have nearly enough capital when the black swan began to emerge in the spring of 2007.

ONE THING THAT surprised me, as I made the rounds of risk experts, was that if you listened closely, their views weren’t really that far from Taleb’s diagnosis of VaR. They agreed with him that VaR didn’t measure the risk of a black swan. And they were critical in other ways as well. Yes, the old way of measuring capital requirements needed updating, but it was crazy to base it on a firm’s internal VaR, partly because that VaR was not set by regulators and partly because it obviously didn’t gauge the kind of extreme events that destroy capital and create a liquidity crisis — precisely the moment when you need cash on hand.( I AGREE )

Indeed, Ethan Berman, the chief executive of RiskMetrics (and no relation to Gregg Berman), told me that one of VaR’s flaws, which only became obvious in this crisis, is that it didn’t measure liquidity risk( A CALLING RUN ) — and of course a liquidity crisis is exactly what we’re in the middle of right now. One reason nobody seems to know how to deal with this kind of crisis is because nobody envisioned it.( WAIT. THAT WAS WHAT LTCM WAS. A CALLING RUN WAS EXACTLY WHAT THEY SHOULD HAVE FEARED SINCE THEY WERE, AND READ THIS CAREFULLY, LOWERING CAPITAL STANDARDS. IS THERE ANYTHING COMPLICATED IN WHAT I'M SAYING? )

In a crisis, Brown, the risk manager at AQR, said, “you want to know who can kill you and whether or not they will and who you can kill if necessary. You need to have an emergency backup plan that assumes everyone is out to get you. In peacetime, you think about other people’s intentions. In wartime, only their capabilities matter. VaR is a peacetime statistic( SILLY. IT WAS A TOOL THAT WAS MISUSED. ).”

VaR DIDN’T GET EVERYTHING right even in what it purported to measure. All the triple-A-rated mortgage-backed securities churned out by Wall Street firms and that turned out to be little more than junk? VaR didn’t see the risk because it generally relied on a two-year data history( THAT ALONE SHOULD LEAD YOU TO DISTRUST IT FOR ANY MAJOR RISK ASSESSMENT. COME ON. ). Although it took into account the increased risk brought on by leverage( OBVIOUSLY IT DIDN'T, BECAUSE IT DIDN'T EVEN CONTEMPLATE A CALLING RUN. ), it failed to distinguish between leverage that came from long-term, fixed-rate debt — bonds and such that come due at a set date — and loans that can be called in at any time and can, as Brown put it “blow you up in two minutes.” That is, the kind of leverage that disappeared the minute something bad arose.( A CALLING RUN. )

“The old adage, ‘garbage in, garbage out’ certainly applies,” Groz said. “When you realize that VaR is using tame historical data to model a wildly different environment, the total losses of Bear Stearns’ hedge funds become easier to understand. It’s like the historic data only has rainstorms and then a tornado hits( ACTUALLY THEY USED WEATHER DATA TO MODEL SOME OF THE RISK. SILLY. ).”

Guldimann, the great VaR proselytizer, sounded almost mournful when he talked about what he saw as another of VaR’s shortcomings. To him, the big problem was that it turned out that VaR could be gamed( FRAUD ). That is what happened when banks began reporting their VaRs. To motivate managers, the banks began to compensate them not just for making big profits but also for making profits with low risks. That sounds good in principle, but managers began to manipulate( FRAUD ) the VaR by loading up on what Guldimann calls “asymmetric risk positions.” These are products or contracts that, in general, generate small gains and very rarely have losses. But when they do have losses, they are huge. These positions made a manager’s VaR look good because VaR ignored the slim likelihood of giant losses, which could only come about in the event of a true catastrophe. A good example was a credit-default swap, which is essentially insurance that a company won’t default( WAIT A MINUTE. THE WHOLE POINT OF A CDS IS TO CONTEMPLATE FORECLOSURE OR DEFAULT. ). The gains made from selling credit-default swaps are small and steady — and the chance of ever having to pay off that insurance was assumed to be minuscule( SILLY ). It was outside the 99 percent probability, so it didn’t show up in the VaR number. People didn’t see the size of those hidden positions lurking in that 1 percent that VaR didn’t measure.

EVEN MORE CRITICAL, it did not properly account for leverage( AGAIN. THAT'S THE WHOLE POINT OF A CDS AS OPPOSED TO JUST REGULAR INSURANCE. ) that was employed through the use of options. For example, said Groz, if an asset manager borrows money to buy shares of a company, the VaR would usually increase. But say he instead enters into a contract that gives someone the right to sell him those shares at a lower price at a later time — a put option. In that case, the VaR might remain unchanged. From the outside, he would look as if he were taking no risk, but in fact, he is( THAT'S NEGLIGENCE. ). If the share price of the company falls steeply, he will have lost a great deal of money. Groz called this practice “stuffing risk into the tails.”

And yet, instead of dismissing VaR as worthless, most of the experts I talked to defended it. The issue, it seemed to me, was less what VaR did and did not do, but how you thought about it. Taleb says that because VaR didn’t measure the 1 percent, it was worse than useless — it was downright harmful( IN THE WRONG HANDS. HE'S CALLING THESE PEOPLE IDIOTS. ). But most of the risk experts said there was a great deal to be said for being able to manage risk 99 percent of the time, however imperfectly, even though it meant you couldn’t account for the last 1 percent.

“If you say that all risk is unknowable,” Gregg Berman said, “you don’t have the basis of any sort of a bet or a trade. You cannot buy and sell anything unless you have some idea of the expectation of how it will move( TRUE ).” In other words, if you spend all your time thinking about black swans, you’ll be so risk averse you’ll never do a trade. Brown put it this way: “NT” — that is how he refers to Nassim Nicholas Taleb — “says that 1 percent will dominate your outcomes. I think the other 99 percent does matter. There are things you can do to control your risk( TRUE ). To not use VaR is to say that I won’t care about the 99 percent, in which case you won’t have a business. That is true even though you know the fate of the firm is going to be determined by some huge event. When you think about disasters, all you can rely on is the disasters of the past. And yet you know that it will be different in the future. How do you plan for that?”( BAGEHOT'S PRINCIPLES SIR )

One risk-model critic, Richard Bookstaber, a hedge-fund risk manager and author of “A Demon of Our Own Design,” ranted about VaR for a half-hour over dinner one night. Then he finally said, “If you put a gun to my head and asked me what my firm’s risk was, I would use VaR.” VaR may have been a flawed number, but it was the best number anyone had come up with.

Of course, the experts I was speaking to were, well, experts. They had a deep understanding of risk modeling and all its inherent limitations. They thought about it all the time. Brown even thought VaR was good when the numbers seemed “off,” or when it started to “miss” on a regular basis — it either meant that there was something wrong with the way VaR was being calculated, or it meant the market was no longer acting “normally.” Either way, he said, it told you something useful( THAT'S ALL THAT MODELS OR THEORIES CAN EVER DO ).

“When I teach it,” Christopher Donohue, the managing director of the research group at the Global Association of Risk Professionals, said, “I immediately go into the shortcomings. You can’t calculate a VaR number and think you know everything you need( TRUE ). On a day-to-day basis I don’t care so much that the VaR is 42. I care about where it was yesterday and where it is going tomorrow. What direction is the risk going?” Then he added, “That is probably another danger: because we put a dollar number to it, they attach a meaning to it( GOOD POINT ).”

By “they,” Donohue meant everyone who wasn’t a risk manager or a risk expert. There were the investors who saw the VaR numbers in the annual reports but didn’t pay them the least bit of attention. There were the regulators who slept soundly in the knowledge that, thanks to VaR, they had the whole risk thing under control. There were the boards who heard a VaR number once or twice a year and thought it sounded good. There were chief executives like O’Neal and Prince. There was everyone, really, who, over time, forgot that the VaR number was only meant to describe what happened 99 percent of the time. That $50 million wasn’t just the most you could lose 99 percent of the time. It was the least you could lose 1 percent of the time. In the bubble, with easy profits being made and risk having been transformed into mathematical conceit, the real meaning of risk had been forgotten. Instead of scrutinizing VaR for signs of impending trouble, they took comfort in a number and doubled down, putting more money at risk in the expectation of bigger gains. “It has to do with the human condition,” said one former risk manager. “People like to have one number they can believe in( THIS IS ANOTHER WAY OF SAYING THAT PEOPLE WERE PREDISPOSED TO EXTEND RISK, AND VAR GAVE THEM THE EXCUSE. HOWEVER, NOTHING FORCES YOU TO EXTEND RISK OR THROW OUT INVESTING AND BANKING COMMON SENSE. ).”

Brown told me: “You absolutely could see it coming( I AGREE ). You could see the risks rising( I AGREE ). However, in the two years before the crisis hit, instead of preparing for it, the opposite took place to an extreme degree. The real trouble we got into today is because of things that took place in the two years before, when the risk measures were saying that things were getting bad( I AGREE ).”

At most firms, risk managers are not viewed as “profit centers,” so they lack the clout of the moneymakers on the trading desks. That was especially true at the tail end of the bubble, when firms were grabbing for every last penny of profit.

At the height of the bubble, there was so much money to be made that any firm that pulled back because it was nervous about risk would forsake huge short-term gains and lose out to less cautious rivals. The fact that VaR didn’t measure the possibility of an extreme event was a blessing to the executives. It made black swans all the easier to ignore( NEGLIGENCE ). All the incentives — profits, compensation, glory, even job security — went in the direction of taking on more and more risk, even if you half suspected it would end badly( THIS IS WHERE GOVERNMENT GUARANTEES COME IN ). After all, it would end badly for everyone else too( THIS IS WHERE GOVERNMENT GUARANTEES COME IN ). As the former Citigroup chief executive Charles Prince famously put it, “As long as the music is playing, you’ve got to get up and dance.” Or, as John Maynard Keynes once wrote, a “sound banker” is one who, “when he is ruined, is ruined in a conventional and orthodox way.”

MAYBE IT WOULD HAVE been different if the people in charge had a better understanding of risk. Maybe it would have helped if Wall Street hadn’t turned VaR into something it was never meant to be. “If we stick with the Dennis Weatherstone example,” Ethan Berman says, “he recognized that he didn’t have the transparency into risk that he needed to make a judgment( THAT'S THE TICKET ). VaR gave him that, and he and his managers could make judgments. To me, that is how it should work. The role of VaR is as one input into that process. It is healthy for the head of the firm to have that kind of information. But people need to have incentives to give him that information( WHAT'S THEIR JOB? ).”

Which brings me back to David Viniar and Goldman Sachs. “VaR is a useful tool,” he said as our interview was nearing its end. “The more liquid the asset( YES ), the better the tool. The more history( YES ), the better the tool. The less of both, the worse it is. It helps you understand what you should expect to happen on a daily basis in an environment that is roughly the same. We had a trade last week in the mortgage universe where the VaR was $1 million. The same trade a week later had a VaR of $6 million. If you tell me my risk hasn’t changed — I say yes it has!” Two years ago, VaR worked for Goldman Sachs the way it once worked for Dennis Weatherstone — it gave the firm a signal that allowed it to make a judgment about risk. It wasn’t the only signal, but it helped. It wasn’t just the math that helped Goldman sidestep the early decline of mortgage-backed instruments. But it wasn’t just judgment either. It was both. The problem on Wall Street at the end of the housing bubble is that all judgment was cast aside. The math alone was never going to be enough.( TRUE )

Like most firms, Goldman does have other models to test for the fat tails. But even Goldman has been caught flat-footed by the crisis, struggling with liquidity, turning itself into a bank holding company and even, at one dire moment, struggling to combat rumors that it would be the next to fall.

“The question is: how extreme is extreme?” Viniar said. “Things that we would have thought were so extreme have happened. We used to say, What will happen if every equity market in the world goes down by 30 percent at the same time? We used to think of that as an extreme event — except that now it has happened. Nothing ever happens until it happens for the first time.”( LTCM. THE S & L CRISIS. )

Which didn’t mean you couldn’t use risk models to sniff out risks. You just had to know that there were risks they didn’t sniff out — and be ever vigilant for the dragons. When Wall Street stopped looking for dragons, nothing was going to save it. Not even VaR.

Joe Nocera is a business columnist for The Times and a staff writer for the magazine."

It's good post, with some good points, but it still didn't mention fraud or government guarantees, for instance. This pathetic view of math models is so silly that going over it again and again seems like overkill, but maybe it isn't. In the end, the math models didn't cause the problem. People did. Even the most basic explantion, that the models fooled people, I consider to be negilgence, since the inherent risk of leveraging is apparent to everyone, including people being paid millions for managing investments.