Showing posts with label Malkiel. Show all posts
Showing posts with label Malkiel. Show all posts

Sunday, June 7, 2009

if a smart guy like Burton Malkiel had to wait for the Internet bubble to end to realize we had been in one

TO BE NOTED: From the NY Times:

"Talking Business

Poking Holes in a Theory on Markets

For some months now, Jeremy Grantham, a respected market strategist with GMO, an institutional asset management company, has been railing about — of all things — the efficient market hypothesis.

You know what the efficient market hypothesis is, don’t you? It’s a theory that grew out of the University of Chicago’s finance department, and long held sway in academic circles, that the stock market can’t be beaten on any consistent basis because all available information is already built into stock prices. The stock market, in other words, is rational.

In the last decade, the efficient market hypothesis, which had been near dogma since the early 1970s, has taken some serious body blows. First came the rise of the behavioral economists, like Richard H. Thaler at the University of Chicago and Robert J. Shiller at Yale, who convincingly showed that mass psychology, herd behavior and the like can have an enormous effect on stock prices — meaning that perhaps the market isn’t quite so efficient after all. Then came a bit more tangible proof: the dot-com bubble, quickly followed by the housing bubble. Quod erat demonstrandum.

These days, you would be hard-pressed to find anybody, even on the University of Chicago campus, who would claim that the market is perfectly efficient. Yet Mr. Grantham, who was a critic of the efficient market hypothesis long before such criticism was in vogue, has hardly been mollified by its decline. In his view, it did a lot of damage in its heyday — damage that we’re still dealing with. How much damage? In Mr. Grantham’s view, the efficient market hypothesis is more or less directly responsible for the financial crisis.

“In their desire for mathematical order and elegant models,” he wrote in his firm’s quarterly letter to clients earlier this year, “the economic establishment played down the role of bad behavior” — not to mention “flat-out bursts of irrationality.”

He continued: “The incredibly inaccurate efficient market theory was believed in totality by many of our financial leaders, and believed in part by almost all. It left our economic and government establishment sitting by confidently, even as a lethally dangerous combination of asset bubbles, lax controls, pernicious incentives and wickedly complicated instruments led to our current plight. ‘Surely, none of this could be happening in a rational, efficient world,’ they seemed to be thinking. And the absolutely worst part of this belief set was that it led to a chronic underestimation of the dangers of asset bubbles breaking.”

(Mr. Grantham concluded: “Well, it’s nice to get that off my chest again!”)

I couldn’t help thinking about Mr. Grantham’s screed as I was reading Justin Fox’s new book, “The Myth of The Rational Market,” an engaging history of what might be called the rise and fall of the efficient market hypothesis.

Mr. Fox is a business columnist for Time magazine (and a former colleague of mine) who has long been interested in academic finance. His thesis, essentially, is that the efficient marketeers were originally on to a good idea. But sealed off in their academic cocoons — and writing papers in their mathematical jargon — they developed an internal logic quite divorced from market realities. It took a new group of young economists, the behavioralists, to nudge the profession back toward reality.

Mr. Fox argues, echoing Mr. Grantham, that the efficient market hypothesis played an outsize role in shaping how the country thought and acted in the last 30-plus years. But Mr. Fox parts company with him by also arguing that the effect wasn’t necessarily all bad. As for the question of whether an academic theory hatched in Chicago led to the financial crisis, suffice it to say that some questions can never be answered definitively. Which isn’t to say they shouldn’t be asked.

“There are no easy ways to beat the market,” Mr. Fox said when I spoke to him a few days ago. If you want to point to the single best thing the efficient market hypothesis taught us, that is the lesson: we can’t beat the market. Indeed, the vast majority of professional money managers can’t beat the market either, at least not on a regular basis.

As Mr. Fox describes it, much of the early academic work that led to the efficient market theory was aimed at simply showing that most predictive stock charts were glorified voodoo — just because a pattern had developed didn’t mean it would continue, or even that it had any real meaning. Dissertations were written showing how 20 randomly chosen stocks outperformed actively managed mutual funds. (Hence the phrase “random walk,” to connote the near impossibility of beating the market regularly.) Mr. Thaler, the Chicago behavioralist, says that evidence on this point — “the no free lunch principle,” he calls it — is clear and convincing.

In time, this insight led to the rise of passive index funds that simply matched the market instead of trying to beat it. Unless you’re Warren Buffett, an index fund is where you should put your money. Even people who don’t follow that advice know they should.

As it turns out, Mr. Grantham was an early advocate of index funds, mainly for unsophisticated investors who have no hope of beating the market. But he also believes that professionals should do better precisely because, as he puts it, “the market is full of major league inefficiencies.”

“There are incredible aberrations,” he told me over lunch not long ago. “The U.S. housing market in 2007. Japan in the 1980s. Nasdaq. In 2000, growth stocks were three times their fair value. We were quoted in The Economist in 2000 saying that the Nasdaq would drop by 75 percent. In an efficient world, you wouldn’t have that in a lifetime. If the market were truly efficient, it would mean that growth stocks had become permanently more valuable.”

As Mr. Grantham sees it, if professional investors had been willing to acknowledge these aberrations — and trade on the fact that the market was out of whack — they should have been able to beat the market. But thanks to the efficient market hypothesis, no one was willing to call a bubble a bubble — because, after all, stock prices were rational.

“It helped mold the ‘this time it’s different’ mentality,” he said. Indeed, professional money managers who tried to buck the tide wound up losing their jobs — because everybody else was making money by riding the bubble for all it was worth. Meanwhile, government officials, starting with Alan Greenspan, were unwilling to burst the bubble precisely because they were unwilling to even judge that it was a bubble. “Our default reflex is that the world knows what it is doing, and that is extravagant nonsense,” Mr. Grantham said.

But as much as I’ve admired Mr. Grantham’s writings over the years, I think the truth, in this case, is a little more subtle. Given the long history of bubbles, I suspect this crisis would have taken place with or without the aid of the efficient market hypothesis. People thought “it’s different this time” in the 1920s, long before anyone was writing about efficient markets. And over the course of history, professional money managers have been just as fearful of bucking the trend as they were during the Internet bubble.

Mr. Fox sees it somewhat differently. On the one hand, he says, the efficient market theoreticians always assumed that smart market participants would force stock prices to become rational. How? By doing exactly what they don’t do in real life: take the other side of trades if prices get out of whack. Their ivory tower view reflected an idealized market that simply doesn’t exist.

On the other hand, Mr. Fox says, what was truly pernicious about the efficient market hypothesis is the way it allowed us to put asset prices on a pedestal that they never deserved. Stock options — supposedly based on a rational price — became prevalent in part because higher stock prices were supposed to be the rational reward for good performance.

Or take the modern emphasis on market capitalization. “At some point in the early 1990s (or maybe it was in the late 1980s), market capitalization became accepted as the best measure of a company’s importance,” Mr. Fox wrote me in an e-mail message. “Before then it was usually profits or revenue. I think that’s a classic example of the way efficient market theory seeped into popular discourse and shaped how we perceived the world. It wasn’t entirely stupid — profits and revenue are flawed, limited measures, and market value does tell you something useful about a company. But it was another one of the ways in which asset prices came to rule the world, which eventually turned out to be a bad thing.”

A few days ago, I called Burton G. Malkiel, the Princeton economist, to ask him what he thought of Mr. Grantham’s theories. Mr. Malkiel is the author of “A Random Walk Down Wall Street,” surely one of the greatest popularizers of any academic theory that’s ever been written.

“It’s ridiculous” to blame the financial crisis on the efficient market hypothesis, Mr. Malkiel said. “If you are leveraged 33-1, and you’re holding long-term securities and using short-term indebtedness, and then there’s a run on the bank — which is what happened to Bear Stearns — how can you blame that on efficient market theory?”

But then we started talking about bubbles. “I do think bubbles exist,” he said. “The problem with bubbles is that you cannot recognize them in advance. We now know that stock prices were crazy in March of 2000. We know that condo prices were nuts.”

I thought to myself: if a smart guy like Burton Malkiel had to wait for the Internet bubble to end to realize we had been in one, then maybe Mr. Grantham has a point after all."

Wednesday, November 12, 2008

"let us not lose faith in market mechanisms to provide solutions"

Burton Malkiel gives the real answer right off the bat in the FT, and then veers off into a mechanistic explanation, i.e., it's the investments:

"As the world economy struggles to recover from the worst financial crisis since the Great Depression, we are reminded of the fundamental truth that every financial system depends on trust."

Trust. Very good.

"Market participants need to believe that the counterparties they deal with will fulfill their obligations. That trust has been severely damaged as our financial institutions have suffered life-threatening, self- inflicted wounds by purchasing over a trillion dollars of complex mortgage-backed securities, secured by dicey loans and financed on the thinnest of margins with short-term debt."

Problems:
1) Poor loans
2) Too little capital

All done? No.

"There is widespread understanding that the long-run solution must involve substantial deleveraging and recapitalization of our financial institutions. But there is also a popular view that the government should effectively regulate complex derivatives out of existence and impose stringent limitations on executive compensation to curb what critics have described as “the pervasive greed on Wall Street.”

Here, we agree. We need to deleverage and recapitalize, but not micromanage these investments.

After giving a good description of why CDS's are good investments, he says this:

"One problem was that the market mushroomed out of control. One could buy a CDS not only on bonds you owned but even on bonds you didn’t own. Speculators might bet that some risky company might default on its bonds even if they did not own the bonds. Hence the volume of CDS instruments became a multiple of the total value of the actual bonds that were being insured. In fact, the CDS market at its peak totaled over $60 trillion, far larger than the total bond market and almost four times larger than the total capitalisation of all the stocks traded on the New York Stock Exchange."

Now, using the great knowledge of Derivative Dribble, I can say that:
I don't consider these CDS's here mentioned investments, in my sense, so I wouldn't buy them, but they are useful for assessing the likelihood of investments defaulting. So they can have a use, even for someone who doesn't invest in them, like me.

"The CDS market linked financial institutions in such a way that systemic risks to the whole financial system were magnified. "

There's no reason that this can't be measured like disaster insurance is.

"What we need is a shift from the current over-the-counter bilateral CDS market to an exchange-traded market. Contracts should be more “plain vanilla” and standardised. They should be fully collateralised and traded on a central exchange. A central clearing house, backed by capital contributions from the clearing members, should guarantee all contracts. The counterparty for each contract would be the clearing house. Contracts should be marked to the market at least daily and probably even more often. The transparent pricing and volume information provided by exchange trading should eliminate the opacity in the current system. While the new market may well reduce the profitability of current market participants, the advantages of greater liquidity, transparency, and safety should help make the entire financial system stronger, less opaque, and more trustworthy. Already the CME and ICE exchanges have been preparing plans for a CDS market based on these principles."

I agree with all this, but it's already been dealt with by poor loans and more capital.

"The second problem requiring a long-run solution concerns the perverse financial incentives inherent in the current system. It too can be handled without government-mandated compensation limits. Under present arrangements, executives of our financial institutions are often paid extremely large cash bonuses based on their attainment of annual profit goals. It is basically the same system by which hedge fund managers earn incentive payments amounting to a fixed percentage of the funds’ profits."

I would think that real moral hazard and fraud and fiduciary negligence would be more useful than limiting pay, but I do agree with limiting pay. I simply believe these individuals aren't worth the money they're receiving. Period.

"While there have clearly been market failures involved in the current crisis, let us not lose faith in market mechanisms to provide solutions. The US financial markets are the most flexible and innovative in the world and, for all their current problems, they have helped make America an innovation machine. Weakening those markets to calm short-term disruptions would be a serious mistake."

Can't disagree with that. Once again, the problem was solved very easily right at the beginning of the post.